0% found this document useful (0 votes)
18 views

Macroconomics3e Ch11

Uploaded by

olvera419luis
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
18 views

Macroconomics3e Ch11

Uploaded by

olvera419luis
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 33

Principles of Macroeconomics 3e

Chapter 11 THE AGGREGATE DEMAND/AGGREGATE SUPPLY MODEL


PowerPoint Image Slideshow
Ch.11 OUTLINE
• 11.1: Macroeconomic Perspectives on Demand and Supply
• 11.2: Building a Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply
• 11.3: Shifts in Aggregate Supply
• 11.4: Shifts in Aggregate Demand
• 11.5: How the AD/AS Model Incorporates Growth, Unemployment,
and Inflation
• 11.6: Keynes’ Law and Say’s Law in the AD/AS Model
New Home Construction

• At the peak of the housing bubble, many people across the country were able to secure the loans necessary to
build new houses. (Credit: modification of "our house! Again!" by Tim Pierce/Flickr Creative Commons, CC BY 2.0)
New Single Family Houses Sold

• From the early 1990s up through 2005, the number of new single family houses sold rose
steadily.
• In 2006, the number dropped dramatically and this dramatic decline continued through 2011.
• Beginning in 2012, the number of new houses sold began to climb back up, but the levels are
still lower than those of 1990. (Source: U.S. Census Bureau)
11.1 Macroeconomic Perspectives on Demand and Supply
• Macroeconomists are sometimes divided into two groups:

• Supply is the most important determinant of the size of the macroeconomy while
demand just tags along.
-or-
• Demand is the most important factor in the size of the macroeconomy while supply
just tags along.

• A successful economic approach needs to take into account both supply


and demand.
Say’s Law and the Macroeconomics of Supply
• Say’s law is: “Supply creates its own demand.”
• Each time a good or service is produced and sold, it represents income to someone.
• Neoclassical economists - economists who generally emphasize the importance of
aggregate supply in determining the size of the macroeconomy over the long run.
• Say’s law that supply creates its own demand does seem a good approximation for
the long run.
• Over periods of years or decades, as the productive power of an economy to supply goods
and services increases, total demand in the economy grows at roughly the same pace.
• However, over shorter time horizons of a few months or years, recessions or
depressions can occur in which firms, as a group, seem to face a lack of demand for
their products.
Keynes’ Law and the Macroeconomics of Demand
• Keynes’ law: “Demand creates its own supply.”
• The level of GDP in the economy is not primarily determined by the potential of
what the economy can supply, but rather by the amount of total demand.
• Keynes’ law can apply well in the short run of months to years, when many firms
experience either a drop in demand for their output during a recession, or so much
demand that they have trouble producing enough during an economic boom.
• However, if demand was all that mattered, then government could make the
economy larger through increases in government spending or large tax cuts to push
up consumption.
• Economies do face genuine limits to how much they can produce.
11.2 Building a Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

• Aggregate demand/aggregate supply model - a model that shows what determines


total supply or total demand for the economy, and how total demand and total supply
interact at the macroeconomic level.
• Aggregate supply (AS) - the total quantity of output (i.e., real GDP) firms will produce
and sell.
• Aggregate supply (AS) curve - shows the total quantity of output (i.e., real GDP) that
firms will produce and sell at each price level.
• Potential GDP - the maximum quantity that an economy can produce given full
employment of its existing levels of labor, physical capital, technology, and institutions.
• Full-employment GDP - another name for potential GDP, when the economy is
producing at its potential and unemployment is at the natural rate of unemployment.
The Aggregate Supply Curve

• Aggregate supply (AS) slopes up, because as the price level for outputs rises, with the price
of inputs remaining fixed, firms have an incentive to produce more to earn higher profits.
• The potential GDP line shows the maximum that the economy can produce with full
employment of workers and physical capital.
• Discussion Question: How can the AS cross Potential GDP?
The Aggregate Demand Curve
• Aggregate demand (AD) - the amount of total spending on domestic
goods and services in an economy.

• It includes all four components of demand: consumption, investment,


government spending, and net exports (exports minus imports).

• Aggregate demand (AD) curve - shows the total spending on


domestic goods and services at each price level.
The Aggregate Demand Curve, Continued

• Aggregate demand (AD) slopes down, showing that, as the price level rises,
the amount of total spending on domestic goods and services declines.
Combining the Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand Curves

• The intersection of the aggregate supply and aggregate demand curves shows the
equilibrium level of real GDP and the equilibrium price level in the economy.
• The equilibrium, where aggregate supply (AS) equals aggregate demand (AD), occurs at
a price level of 90 and an output level of 8,800.
Interpreting the AD/AS Model

• Using a hypothetical equilibrium, with price level at 130 and real GDP at $680, what
information can we infer about the state of this country’s economy?
• Is this country risking inflationary pressures or facing high unemployment? How can you
tell?
Defining SRAS and LRAS
• Short run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve - positive short run
relationship between the price level for output and real GDP, holding
the prices of inputs fixed

• Long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve - vertical line at potential


GDP showing no relationship between the price level for output and
real GDP in the long run.
11.3 Shifts in Aggregate Supply
• Two of the most important factors that can lead to shifts in the AS curve:
• productivity growth
• changes in input prices

• The aggregate supply curve can also shift due to unexpected shocks to
input goods or labor.
• Examples: large weather events affecting crops or an overseas war that requires a
large number people to fight instead of work.

• Stagflation - an economy experiences stagnant growth and high inflation


at the same time.
Illustrated: Shifts in Aggregate Supply

• For graph (a): The rise in productivity causes the SRAS curve to shift to the right. The original equilibrium
E0 is at the intersection of AD and SRAS0.
• When SRAS shifts right, then the new equilibrium E1 is at the intersection of AD and SRAS1, and then yet
another equilibrium, E2, is at the intersection of AD and SRAS2.
• Shifts in SRAS to the right, lead to a greater level of output and to downward pressure on the price level.
Illustrated: Shifts in Aggregate Supply, Continued

• For graph (b): A higher price for inputs means that at any given price level for outputs, a lower real
GDP will be produced so aggregate supply will shift to the left from SRAS 0 to SRAS1.
• The new equilibrium, E1, has a reduced quantity of output and a higher price level than the original
equilibrium (E0).
11.4 Shifts in Aggregate Demand
• Remember that the components of aggregate demand are:
• consumption spending
• investment spending
• government spending
• spending on exports minus imports.

• A shift of the AD curve to the right means that at least one of these components
increased so that a greater amount of total spending would occur at every price level.

• A shift of the AD curve to the left means that at least one of these components
decreased so that a lesser amount of total spending would occur at every price level.
How Changes by Consumers and Firms Can Affect AD

• When consumers feel more confident about the future of the


economy, they tend to consume more.

• If business confidence is high, then firms tend to spend more on


investment, believing that the future payoff will be substantial.

• Conversely, if consumer or business confidence drops, then


consumption and investment spending declines.
Illustrated: Shifts in Aggregate Demand

• For graph (a) :An increase in consumer confidence or business confidence can shift AD to the right, from
AD0 to AD1.
• When AD shifts to the right, the new equilibrium (E1) will have a higher quantity of output and also a
higher price level compared with the original equilibrium (E0).
• In this example, the new equilibrium (E1) is also closer to potential GDP.
• An increase in government spending or a cut in taxes that leads to a rise in consumer spending can also
shift AD to the right.
Illustrated: Shifts in Aggregate Demand, Continued

• For graph (b): A decrease in consumer confidence or business confidence can shift AD to the left, from AD0 to
AD1.
• When AD shifts to the left, the new equilibrium (E1) will have a lower quantity of output and also a lower
price level compared with the original equilibrium (E0).
• In this example, the new equilibrium (E1) is also farther below potential GDP.
• A decrease in government spending or higher taxes that leads to a fall in consumer spending can also shift AD
to the left.
How Government Macroeconomic Policy Choices Can Shift AD
• Higher government spending will cause AD to shift to the right, while lower
government spending will cause AD to shift to the left.

• Tax cuts for individuals will tend to increase consumption demand, while tax
increases will tend to diminish it.

• Tax policy can also pump up investment demand by offering lower tax rates for
corporations or tax reductions that benefit specific kinds of investment.

• During a recession, when unemployment is high and many businesses are suffering
low profits or even losses, the U.S. often passes tax cuts.
Recession and Full Employment in the AD/AS Model
• Whether the economy is in a recession is
illustrated in the AD/AS model by how
close the equilibrium is to the potential
GDP line as indicated by the vertical
LRAS line.
• In this example, the level of output Y0 at
the equilibrium E0 is relatively far from
the potential GDP line, so it can
represent an economy in recession, well
below the full employment level of GDP.
• In contrast, the level of output Y1 at the
equilibrium E1 is relatively close to
potential GDP, and so it would represent
an economy with a lower unemployment
rate.
11.5 How the AD/AS Model Incorporates Growth, Unemployment,
and Inflation

Growth and Recession in the AD/AS Diagram:


• In the AD/AS diagram, long-run economic growth due to productivity increases over time
will be represented by a gradual shift to the right of aggregate supply.

• The vertical line representing potential GDP (or the “full employment level of GDP”) will
gradually shift to the right over time as well.

• The AD/AS diagram illustrates recessions when the equilibrium level of real GDP is
substantially below potential GDP.

• In years of resurgent economic growth the equilibrium will typically be close to potential
GDP.
Unemployment in the AD/AS Diagram
• Remember, there are two types of unemployment:
• Short run variations in unemployment (cyclical unemployment) caused by the
business cycle as economy expands and contracts.
• Long run unemployment rate (typically hovers around 5% in U.S.) when the
economy is healthy.

• The AD/AS diagram shows cyclical unemployment by how close the


economy is to the potential or full GDP employment level.
• Low cyclical unemployment for an economy occurs when the level of output is
close to potential GDP.
• High cyclical unemployment arises when the output is substantially to the left of
potential GDP.
Inflationary Pressures in the AD/AS Diagram
• Inflation fluctuates in the short run.
• Higher inflation rates have typically occurred either during or just after
economic booms.
• Rates of inflation generally decline during recessions.
• The AD/AS framework implies two ways that inflationary pressures may
arise:
• If the aggregate demand continues to shift to the right when the economy is
already at or near potential GDP and full employment, thus pushing the
equilibrium into the AS curve's steep portion.
• A rise in input prices that affects many or most firms across the economy (e.g., oil
or labor) and causes the aggregate supply curve to shift back to the left.
Sources of Inflationary Pressure in the AD/AS Model

In graph (a):
• A shift in aggregate demand, from AD0 to AD1, when it happens in the area of the SRAS curve that is
near potential GDP, will lead to a higher price level, leading to inflation.

• The new equilibrium (E1) is at a higher price level (P1) than the original equilibrium.
Sources of Inflationary Pressure in the AD/AS Model, Continued

In graph (b):
• A shift in aggregate supply, from SRAS0 to SRAS1, will lead to a lower real GDP and to pressure for a higher
price level and inflation.

• The new equilibrium (E1) is at a higher price level (P1), while the original equilibrium (E0) is at the lower
price level (P0).
11.6 Keynes’ Law and Say’s Law in the AD/AS Model

• We can use the AD/AS model to illustrate both Say’s law and Keynes’ law.
• This approach of dividing the SRAS curve into different zones works as a
diagnostic test that we can apply to an economy.
The Keynesian Zone
• Keynesian zone - portion of the SRAS curve where GDP is far below
potential and the SRAS curve is flat

• If the AD curve crosses a portion of the SRAS curve in the Keynesian


zone, the equilibrium level of real GDP is far below potential GDP, so:
• the economy is in recession,
• cyclical unemployment is high,
• inflationary price pressure is not much of a worry
The Neoclassical Zone
• Neoclassical zone - portion of the SRAS curve where GDP is at or near
potential output where the SRAS curve is steep.

• If the AD curve crosses a portion of the SRAS curve in the neoclassical


zone, the equilibrium is near potential GDP, so:
• cyclical unemployment is low (structural unemployment may remain an
issue),
• the only way to increase the size of the real GDP is for AS to shift to the right,
• shifts in AD will create pressures to change the price level.
The Intermediate Zone
• Intermediate zone - portion of the SRAS curve where GDP is below
potential but not so far below as in the Keynesian zone; the SRAS curve
is upward-sloping, but not vertical in the intermediate zone.

• If the AD curve crosses a portion of the SRAS curve in the intermediate


zone, we expect unemployment and inflation to move in opposing
directions.
• A shift of AD to the right will move output closer to potential GDP:
• Reduce unemployment
• Higher price level and upward pressure on inflation.
• A shift of AD to the left will move output further from potential GDP:
• Raise unemployment
• Lower price level and downward pressure on inflation.

You might also like