Long_term_Econ_Factors_Aggregate_D_S
Long_term_Econ_Factors_Aggregate_D_S
Say’s law
“supply creates its own demand”
Keynes’ law
“demand creates its own supply”
SAY’S LAW
At the peak of the housing bubble, many people across the country were able to secure
the loans necessary to build new houses. (Credit: modification of work by Tim
Pierce/Flickr Creative Commons)
FIGURE 24.2
From the early 1990s up through 2005, the number of new single family houses sold
rose steadily. In 2006, the number dropped dramatically and this dramatic decline
continued through 2011. By 2014, the number of new houses sold had begun to climb
back up, but the levels are still lower than those of 1990. (Source: U.S. Census Bureau)
1. MACROECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES ON
DEMAND AND SUPPLY
Aggregate demand (AD) slopes down, showing that, as the price level rises, the
amount of total spending on domestic goods and services declines.
THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND POTENTIAL GDP
Aggregate supply (AS) slopes up, because as the price level for outputs rises, with the
price of inputs remaining fixed, firms have an incentive to produce more and to earn
higher profits.
The potential GDP line shows the maximum that the economy can produce with full
employment of workers and physical capital.
WHY DOES AS CROSS POTENTIAL GDP?
The diagram's horizontal axis shows real GDP—that is, the level of GDP adjusted for inflation. The
vertical axis shows the price level, which measures the average price of all goods and services
produced in the economy.
In other words, the price level in the AD-AS model is what we called the GDP Deflator.
Remember that the price level is different from the inflation rate.
Visualize the price level as an index number, like the Consumer Price Index, while the inflation
rate is the percentage change in the price level over time.
EQUILIBRIUM
The equilibrium, where aggregate supply (AS) equals aggregate demand (AD), occurs
at a price level of 90 and an output level of 8,800.
DEFINING SRAS AND LRAS
(a) The rise in productivity causes the AS curve to shift to the right. The original equilibrium E0 is at the
intersection of AD and AS0. When AS shifts right, then the new equilibrium E1 is at the intersection
of AD and AS1, and then yet another equilibrium, E2, is at the intersection of AD and AS2. Shifts in
AS to the right, lead to a greater level of output and to downward pressure on the price level.
(b) A higher price for inputs means that at any given price level for outputs, a lower quantity will be
produced so aggregate supply will shift to the left from AS0 to AS1. The new equilibrium, E1, has a
reduced quantity of output and a higher price level than the original equilibrium (E0).
4. SHIFT IN AD (FIGURE 24.8)
(a) An increase in consumer confidence or business confidence can shift AD to the right, from AD0 to AD1. When AD
shifts to the right, the new equilibrium (E1) will have a higher quantity of output and also a higher price level
compared with the original equilibrium (E0). In this example, the new equilibrium (E1) is also closer to potential GDP.
An increase in government spending or a cut in taxes that leads to a rise in consumer spending can also shift AD to
the right.
(b) A decrease in consumer confidence or business confidence can shift AD to the left, from AD0 to AD1. When AD shifts
to the left, the new equilibrium (E1) will have a lower quantity of output and aslso a lower price level compared with
the original equilibrium (E0). In this example, the new equilibrium (E1) is also farther below potential GDP. A decrease
in government spending or higher taxes that leads to a fall in consumer spending can also shift AD to the left.
5. HOW THE AD/AS MODEL INCORPORATES GROWTH,
UNEMPLOYMENT, AND INFLATION phải indicate 3 đều này
nếu explain AD/AS model
By the end of this section, you will be able to:
1. Use the aggregate demand/aggregate supply model to show periods
of economic growth and recession
2. Explain how unemployment and inflation impact the aggregate
demand/aggregate supply model
3. Evaluate the importance of the aggregate demand/aggregate supply
model
The AD/AS model can convey a number of interlocking relationships
between the three macroeconomic goals of growth, unemployment,
and low inflation.
Moreover, the AD/AS framework is flexible enough to accommodate both
the Keynes’ law approach that focuses on aggregate demand and the
short run, while also including the Say’s law approach that focuses on
aggregate supply and the long run.
These advantages are considerable. Every model is a simplified version
of the deeper reality and, in the context of the AD/AS model, the three
macroeconomic goals arise in ways that are sometimes indirect or
incomplete.
GROWTH AND RECESSION IN THE AD/AS DIAGRAM
(a) A shift in aggregate demand, from AD0 to AD1, when it happens in the area of the AS
curve that is near potential GDP, will lead to a higher price level and to pressure for a
higher price level and inflation. The new equilibrium (E1) is at a higher price level (P1)
than the original equilibrium.
(b) A shift in aggregate supply, from AS0 to AS1, will lead to a lower real GDP and to
pressure for a higher price level and inflation. The new equilibrium (E1) is at a higher
price level (P1), while the original equilibrium (E0) is at the lower price level (P0).
INFLATIONARY PRESSURES IN THE AD/AS DIAGRAM
An alternative source of inflationary pressures can occur due to a rise in input prices
that affects many or most firms across the economy—perhaps an important input to
production like oil or labor—and causes the aggregate supply curve to shift back to the
left. In Figure 24.10 (b), the SRAS curve's shift to the left also increases the price level
from P0 at the original equilibrium (E0) to a higher price level of P1 at the new
equilibrium (E1). In effect, the rise in input prices ends up, after the final output is
produced and sold, passing along in the form of a higher price level for outputs.
The AD/AS diagram shows only a one-time shift in the price level. It does not address
the question of what would cause inflation either to vanish after a year, or to sustain
itself for several years.
There are two explanations for why inflation may persist over time. These two reasons
are interrelated, because if a government fosters a macroeconomic environment with
inflationary pressures, then people will grow to expect inflation. However, the AD/AS
diagram does not show these patterns of ongoing or expected inflation in a direct way.
One way that continual inflationary price increases can occur is if the government
continually attempts to stimulate aggregate demand in a way that keeps pushing the
AD curve when it is already in the SRAS curve's steep portion.
A second possibility is that, if inflation has been occurring for several years, people
might begin to expect a certain level of inflation. If they do, then these expectations will
cause prices, wages and interest rates to increase annually by the amount of the
inflation expected.
6. KEYNES’ LAW AND SAY’S LAW IN THE AD/AS
MODEL
Near the equilibrium Ek, in the Keynesian zone at the far left of the AS curve, small shifts in AD, either to the
right or the left, will affect the output level Yk, but will not much affect the price level. In the Keynesian zone,
AD largely determines the quantity of output.
Near the equilibrium En, in the neoclassical zone at the far right of the AS curve, small shifts in AD, either to
the right or the left, will have relatively little effect on the output level Yn, but instead will have a greater effect
on the price level.
In the neoclassical zone, the near-vertical AS curve close to the level of potential GDP largely determines
the quantity of output. In the intermediate zone around equilibrium Ei, movement in AD to the right will
increase both the output level and the price level, while a movement in AD to the left would decrease both
the output level and the price level.
6. KEYNES’ LAW AND SAY’S LAW IN THE AD/AS MODEL
This approach of dividing the SRAS curve into different zones works
as a diagnostic test that we can apply to an economy, like a doctor
checking a patient for symptoms.
First, figure out in what zone the economy is. This will clarify the
economic issues, tradeoffs, and policy choices. Some economists
believe that the economy is strongly predisposed to be in one zone or
another.
Thus, hard-line Keynesian economists believe that the economies
are in the Keynesian zone most of the time, and so they view the
neoclassical zone as a theoretical abstraction.
Conversely, hard-line neoclassical economists argue that economies
are in the neoclassical zone most of the time and that the Keynesian
zone is a distraction. The Keynesian Perspective and The
Neoclassical Perspective should help to clarify the underpinnings and
consequences of these contrasting views of the macroeconomy.
6. KEYNES’ LAW AND SAY’S LAW IN THE AD/AS MODEL
Focus first on the Keynesian zone, that portion of the SRAS curve on the far left which
is relatively flat. If the AD curve crosses this portion of the SRAS curve at an equilibrium
point like Ek, then certain statements about the economic situation will follow. In the
Keynesian zone, the equilibrium level of real GDP is far below potential GDP, the
economy is in recession, and cyclical unemployment is high. If aggregate demand
shifted to the right or left in the Keynesian zone, it will determine the resulting level of
output (and thus unemployment). However, inflationary price pressure is not much of a
worry in the Keynesian zone, since the price level does not vary much in this zone.
Now, focus your attention on the neoclassical zone of the SRAS curve, which is the
near-vertical portion on the right-hand side. If the AD curve crosses this portion of the
SRAS curve at an equilibrium point like En where output is at or near potential GDP,
then the size of potential GDP pretty much determines the level of output in the
economy. Since the equilibrium is near potential GDP, cyclical unemployment is low in
this economy, although structural unemployment may remain an issue. In the
neoclassical zone, shifts of aggregate demand to the right or the left have little effect on
the level of output or employment. The only way to increase the size of the real GDP in
the neoclassical zone is for AS to shift to the right. However, shifts in AD in the
neoclassical zone will create pressures to change the price level.
Finally, consider the SRAS curve's intermediate zone. If the AD curve crosses this
portion of the SRAS curve at an equilibrium point like Ei, then we might expect
unemployment and inflation to move in opposing directions. For instance, a shift of AD
to the right will move output closer to potential GDP and thus reduce unemployment,
but will also lead to a higher price level and upward pressure on inflation. Conversely, a
shift of AD to the left will move output further from potential GDP and raise
unemployment, but will also lead to a lower price level and downward pressure on
inflation.
TAKE-AWAY