0% found this document useful (0 votes)
58 views

Post-Truth: An Alumni Economist's Perspective: International Review of Applied Economics

Uploaded by

chachasalsabella
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
58 views

Post-Truth: An Alumni Economist's Perspective: International Review of Applied Economics

Uploaded by

chachasalsabella
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 27

International Review of Applied Economics

ISSN: 0269-2171 (Print) 1465-3486 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cira20

Post-truth: an alumni economist’s perspective

Ben Fine

To cite this article: Ben Fine (2019): Post-truth: an alumni economist’s perspective, International
Review of Applied Economics

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/02692171.2019.1617252

Published online: 21 May 2019.

Submit your article to this journal

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cira20
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
https://doi.org/10.1080/02692171.2019.1617252

Post-truth: an alumni economist’s perspective


Ben Fine
Department of Economics, SOAS University of London, London, UK; Wits School of Governance, University
of Witwatersrand, Johannesburg, South Africa

ABSTRACT ARTICLE HISTORY


Drawing upon 50 years as an academic economist, this lecture to Received 18 April 2019
alumni of SOAS’s Department of Economics reflects upon the Accepted 7 May 2019
continual ‘post-truth’ aspects of mainstream economics, ranging KEYWORDS
over its substantive, if shifting, content, and its treatment of Heterodox economics;
methodology and interdisciplinarity. It draws upon a wide range economics imperialism;
of theory, empirical analysis, policy and anecdote to highlight both pluralist economics
the need for alternatives and the continuing, even increased, fail-
ure of the mainstream to engage with criticism and alternatives. JEL CLASSIFICATION
B2; B4; B5

1. Mathematical beginnings
Thanks for the opportunity to give this lecture and, at the same time, mark my
retirement from SOAS after 27 years, following 20 years at Birkbeck, and 50 years
since first studying economics as a graduate student, having completed a first degree in
mathematics. Back in 1969, Jim Mirrlees, then Professor of Economics at Oxford,
visited the Maths Institute to recruit third-year undergraduates to be funded to take
a 2-year postgraduate course in economics. I was one of the lucky ones to benefit from
his view that a degree in mathematics was more important than one in economics for
his purposes. Within a week, I was participating in a weekly research seminar with the
leading mathematical economists organised by Mirrlees, reflecting the ease of transition
from maths to such economics. Of course, sorry for the name dropping and more to
come as this is an occasion to indulge myself, Mirrlees was later to win a Nobel Prize
for devising optimal taxation systems (in which all conscientiously pay their taxes).
That’s how my economics began, and sorry that I have taught so few of you as alumni in
our audience today, as I have scarcely taught other than at postgraduate level, and especially
focused upon research students, with 51of my own having completed, and hundreds of others
have passed through my hands as I have spent most of my career as a research student tutor.
Indeed, I can identify as past supervisees, 10 professors, 21 lecturers, 14 researchers, four I am
now unable to trace, and two whom I am unsure how to categorise!1
Now, from my title, I suspect you expect me to entertain you with Fake News and
Trumponomics. Not at all. I want to talk about my own career and had to find a way to
frame it, a peg or theme on which to hang it, a sort of literature survey of myself (a private
joke with my PhD students).2 I thought it might be interesting to see how my works, 30
books and 300 articles or so, have stood up to the test of time, against my major theme that

CONTACT Ben Fine [email protected]


© 2019 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
2 B. FINE

mainstream economics is a major and long-standing purveyor of post-truth. Here, it is


important to note that the current vogue of pointing to fake news, post-truth, etc, is itself
a fake, post-truth news insofar as it suggests an innocent earlier age of golden truth. It ain’t
so, especially in economics where the broader lesson might be learned of its having
provided the fake news of the past as the foundations for the current decline, if not original
sin, in fall from grace.

2. From the social and the aggregate . . .


Let me begin with my PhD at the London School of Economics, supervised by Amartya
Sen, and a mere 100 pages of maths and one page of references. This was on social
choice theory and, by chance, it was a topic that came up in my first few weeks as
a participant in that weekly seminar. I realised a way of dealing with it, through
intuitionistic logic, and away I went and got a PhD, publications, and a job all within
a few years.3 It was a prominent topic in those days but less so now.4 It is concerned
with the problem of how to create a utility function for society out of those of
individuals. Pause a minute and think about this in terms of our current simple
conundrum about Brexit or not. Just imagine the idea of reducing the shifting complex-
ity of issues, beliefs, and outcomes to the as if preferences of a single-fixed individual
over given alternatives – this is surely a post-truth!
It all began in 1951, with Arrow’s Social Choice and Individual Values for which he
received a Nobel Prize alongside his contribution to General Equilibrium Theory (more
Post-Truth (PT), on this in a bit). Within a few years it was complemented by, if not
originating with, its counterpart in supply, with Robert Solow, another Nobel
Prizewinner, and the use of a production function to reduce (national) production to
a single simple process combining all available resources (single aggregates of capital
and labour alone in most instances), as a way to measure technical progress as
a residual. Now this production function as part of its technical apparatus remains
irreplaceable in the mainstream economist’s toolkit but, beyond a one-sector world, it is
simply invalid for most of its applications as was shown in the Cambridge Capital
Controversy that was finally settled unambiguously in favour of critics just as I was
beginning economics. As Paul Samuelson, another Nobel, closed a special issue on the
topic in the Quarterly Journal of Economics (more on its PT later) in 1966, p. 583:
If all this causes headaches for those nostalgic for the old time parables of neoclassical
writing, we must remind ourselves that scholars are not born to live an easy existence. We
must respect, and appraise, the facts of life.

Who could disagree? Well, Samuelson himself for a start, not least as exactly the same
assumptions underpin the universally deployed notion of comparative advantage as do
those for the Cambridge Critique. But Samuelson suggests that the theory of compara-
tive advantage is probably the only proposition in economics that is at once true and
nontrivial.5 But nor is Samuelson alone in observing the facts, or theories, of life in the
breach. For mainstream economists in typical PT fashion have precisely failed ‘to
respect, and appraise, the facts of life.’ They have simply continued as if the
Cambridge Critique and Samuelson’s conclusion, do not exist, a sort of climate change
denial defence of the production function. The only exception is the very occasional,
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 3

once in a while contribution from heterodoxy asking whatever happened to the


Critique, an indulgence of which I am guilty now and again.6 Where there has been
another major change is that the Quarterly Journal of Economics has abandoned the
search for truth, or possibly debate, as it no longer seems to welcome such critical
commentary. I had two articles returned unrefereed on the grounds that they would not
be of interest to the readership . . . one bent over backwards to use the mathematics of
utility functions to undermine the approach to identity put forward by George Akerlof,
Nobel;, and the other was a critique of the slavish support for Gary Becker’s economics
imperialism put forward by Edward Lazear (it makes economics the only true science
and that is why it is triumphing and taking over all the others – but, if so, why only now
after hundreds of years of the dismal science?). Lazear became Chief Economic Advisor
to George W. Bush.7
But the technical problems that underpin the Cambridge Critique and its production
function are of much broader PT significance, leading to extreme assumptions, taken to
be true because they are necessary to gain desired conclusions, to guarantee the
existence, uniqueness, stability and efficiency of General Equilibrium – never mind,
assume, often implicitly, these conditions are satisfied (we cannot do macro otherwise
as short-run aggregate dynamics); the theory of second best tells us partial movements
towards full equilibrium may make things worse with profound implications for policy-
making; and the theory of (pursuit of) comparative advantage, let alone consumer
surplus and the like, for these depend upon only two goods, no externalities, no
increasing returns to scale, no non-traded goods, full employment, perfect competition,
no multinational corporations, perfect financial markets, . . .. All of this let alone the
conditions necessary to satisfy the aggregation problem, to represent an economy as if
a single individual for which even every individual, producer or consumer being the
same does not even suffice. This is the PT running riot. Much of my work has
theoretically, analytically and for policy purposes sought to take these PTs as
a critical point of departure for alternatives.
But, possibly as a surprise, social choice theory, or at least the techniques that I learnt
or developed, have recurred throughout my work. By accident, reading the papers of
someone applying for a job at Birkbeck, I realised the methods could be used to address
the problem of ‘consumption norms’ – what sort of households commonly consumes
what sort of goods with what sort of priority – so, for example, any household with
a male head is much more likely to have a car, or a single mother head is more likely to
have a phone and video (this was all nearly 30 years ago, when not even a majority of
houses had central heating and few a dishwasher!). This became part and parcel of
work, funded by the ESRC, to explain the relationship between consumption, especially
durables, and female labour market participation – simple comparative advantage of
displacing women’s labour from the home for wages does not work.8 Ultimately, this
led to further research on consumption around the UK Nation’s Diet, also funded by
the ESRC, with work primarily completed over 25 years ago. All of this gave rise to the
System of Provision approach that has become one of the leading ways of looking at
consumption, other than in economics of course where the mutual interactions between
provisioning and consumer culture are PT crunched into given utility functions for
given items of consumption, maybe with a bit of learning, informational asymmetries
and behavioural dimensions these days as token acknowledgement that consumption
4 B. FINE

may be driven by cultures irreducible to given basic urges, and these have themselves to
be identified and explained.9
I am pleased with this work as it suggested relatively early that there is a link between
increasingly poor diet and the food provisioning system. In a nutshell, if you produce
the sugar, the cream, the fat, the salt and so on, someone has to consume it. All dietary
advice does is to shift the incidence, and it can make things worse not better as the ones
best able to act upon the advice tend to be the least vulnerable to needing and inclining
to indulge themselves through cheap food. Thus, for example, those who were healthily
buying the newly available-skimmed milks in hypemarkets were also buying the cream
desserts and fancy cheeses; a diet coke justifies a hamburger, and so on. My research
identified that contemporary capitalism had uniquely reconciled and promoted the
imperatives to eat and to diet, giving rise not only to eating disorders but also to
a situation in which there is more malnutrition in the world today from over-than
under-eating, and corresponding diseases are of global epidemic proportions, with
dramatic implications for well-being and burdens on health systems. I have some
pride if not satisfaction in anticipating this.10
This was not just an academic exercise as I joined the newly-founded Social Science
Research Committee of the UK’s Food Standards Agency in 2008. Before it had even
met, the Cameron Government took away responsibility for diet and labelling, leaving it
with only hygiene and safety. It has since been transformed away from an ethos of
addressing the food system into one of promoting informed consumer choice with
otherwise little, no or negative impact if leaving regulation of the provisioning of food
untouched beyond health and safety and labelling. With revolving doors between
government, advisors, politics, the media and corporate managers, it is a moot point
whether the state regulates business or business regulates the state, not just for food but,
as found in other work, across the water, housing, health, rail, pensions, and finance. As
a footnote, having served three three-year terms on the Committee (including chairing
its Slaughterhouse Controls Working Group just as the horsemeat scandal broke), the
Committee’s capacity to set its own agenda was taken away. I could have continued but
had enough . . . By the way, just do not start me on food and Brexit, but nearly all the
vets inspecting slaughterhouses are Spanish trainees, just one straw in the haystack of
what will not be in place as we enter, if we do, our new world of self-determination and
sovereignty.
My training in social choice theory has also been revisited over the past year for
a major programme of work for Oxfam on inequality, not just for income and
wealth, but across the many different dimensions of economic and social well-being.
Simple conceptual issues over how to assess the worth of increases or decreases in
provision for and across individuals have been addressed, as well as how to decom-
pose inequality into the sum of intra-group and inter-group inequality. These are
extraordinarily demanding technical issues, amenable to some degree of mathema-
tical complexity but elegance; and, yet, with economics defined as the allocation of
scarce resources between competing ends, and a dogmatic belief in the separation
between positive and normative economics, economics has depended heavily on the
PT that it is ethically neutral. I recall Solow telling me just because he believes the
rate of profit is determined by the marginal product of capital, it does not mean he
feels it just for capitalists to collect it whilst driving around in Cadillacs. But just that
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 5

definition of economics as allocation of scarce resources between competing ends is


haemorrhaging values, as is the alternative definition that economics is the study of
the levels and forms taken by exploitation and corresponding consequences. What is
interesting here is not whether economics can be value-free but why the discipline
holds to the PT that it can be, thereby totally disregarding its ethical
underpinnings.11

3. . . . to the state and the systemic


Moving on, not least as the social choice has occupied a minor part of my academic life
in research and altogether in teaching, consider not just the PT state of economics but
also the PT economics of the state. Looking for the origins of British state intervention
in the interwar period, research over a long period focused on the coal industry, and
this was carried forward to the post-war nationalisation and privatisation, funded by
ESRC and Leverhulme. Here, the default position is the market works well if not
perfectly. I did in one leading scholar’s judgement settle a debate over the interwar
disastrous performance of the industry by demonstrating that it failed to accrue the
economies of scale and mechanisation, falling behind all of its rivals. But my major
innovation was to implicate the private ownership of the coal in the ground as a major
factor, essentially acting as a tax on upgrading.12 From Ricardo onwards, this has been
seen as potentially inequitable but not as a source of major dynamic impediment and
inefficiency. Even the 1938 Tory Government thought otherwise, nationalising the
ownership of coal at a price of £66m, or well over £4 billion in today’s money. My
work on the inefficiencies imposed by land in mineral development was extended to oil
and to diamonds, in one of my favourite pieces because it has pictures, rare in my work,
if mainly overlooked.13 In Figures 1 and 2 below you see how rapidly oil extraction
became inefficiently fragmented at the town of Spindletop (or perhaps it should have
been called Spindletops). The other sketch in Figure 3 below is of the Kimberley
Diamond mine, a huge hole in the ground but equally inefficiently fragmented (espe-
cially when you realise the rope and pulley systems separately connecting each of the
spaces above the Big Hole are the means to extract kimberlite in the search for
diamonds). My argument for coal is that rather than over a few years, but over
centuries, exactly the same sorts of inefficiencies evolved into place across the privately
owned but initially relatively spacious landed estates, not least as mines extended
geographically across properties as coal was extracted.
And here I would like to reference what I consider the two best books I have read
over the last decade, both by the same author, Brett Christophers (2013, 2018); one
deciphers how national statistics have been reinterpreted to include financial activity as
a component (rather than a transfer or exploitation as some of us would have it) and his
more recent account of how half of UK state ownership of land has been privatised
since Thatcher (10% of the country with the same amount still to go), with scarcely
a squeak of recognition or opposition even though dominating all other privatisations
by value. Perhaps SOAS will make its own contribution from its estate if and when it
goes under.
Here in the figures, though, we have what I have recently called the economics of
excess, most notable in the proliferation of producers, and fragmentation of production,
6 B. FINE

Figure 1. Spindletop gusher*.


Spindletop, the astounding southeast Texas gusher which changed the history of America and the world on
10 January 1901. Flowing 100 000 barrels a day from a depth of 1020 feet, in a solid black stream 175 feet in the
air, it proved that there was an abundance of oil in the earth. Reproduced with permission from Ohio University Press
and Knowles.

Figure 2. Boiler Avenue at Spindletop*.


1903. Horses and carts travel down the plank road called Boiler Avenue which provided access to Spindletop’s boiler
locations. Wells were drilled so close together that a man could walk from one rig floor to another without ever
touching the ground. Every well was a gusher. Reproduced with permission from Ohio University Press and Knowles.

but equally evident in overeating and the diseases of affluence, as well as climate change,
and most notable of all and underpinning the acceleration of each of the others, excess
in finance, or financialisation. This is something I have been working on for nearly 20
years, and it is a concept that has exploded across the social sciences, from systemic
analysis of neoliberalism to the material cultures of everyday household lives of credit
card indebtedness and subprime.14 Yet, it is a concept that simply does not exist in PT
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 7

Figure 3. Kimberley Mine*.


Diagram of claim ownership, Kimberley mine, 1877. Reproduced with permission from Yale University Press.* All figures
reproduced from Fine (1994) ‘Coal, Diamonds and Oil: Towards a Comparative Theory of Mining’, Review of Political
Economy, vol 6, no 3, pp. 279–302.

mainstream economics,15 as opposed to heterodoxy. This is because of its inability to


deal with the systemic and its grounding within optimising individuals, efficiency and
equilibrium even if as points of mild critical departure. Becoming more real by depart-
ing from the efficient-market hypothesis (EMH) to what I call the IEMH (InEfficient
Market Hypothesis) whether through informational or behavioural ‘imperfections’ does
not begin to get to grips with the way that finance has got to grips with economic,
political and ideological power.

4. And the micro-foundations of macro or the other way about?


I have now opened up not so much a can as a container of worms in and around the
role and understanding of the state. The mainstream’s preferred PT in this respect is
to confine it to macro and micro, both confining the macro in and of itself, then to
micro and then to confine micro. For macro, then never mind the total bastardisa-
tion of Keynes’ own rich thinking through the IS/LM framework that dominated
post-war macro, the monetarist counterrevolution and ultimately the New Classical
Economics took PT extremes to further extremes, with representative individuals,
perfectly working markets, rational expectations, and a state so denuded in these
denuded circumstances that it became unsurprisingly ineffective. Make assumptions
that render the state powerless, and lo and behold you believe the market works best.
But, representative individuals means no distribution. With real business cycle
theory, technical change is a random shock, and that the contemporary global
economy is run by a few hundred corporations, two-thirds of which are financial,
is an unobserved truth. The PT involved here involves the framing of macro as
micro as observed. Nobel laureate Robert Lucas (1981, 108) famously put it, ‘the
term “macroeconomic” will simply disappear from use and the modifier “micro” will
be superfluous’.
Further, as opposed to stochastic risk which is the only thing that keeps you out of
permanent equilibrium, ‘in cases of uncertainty economic reasoning will be of no value’,
8 B. FINE

Lucas (1981, p. 224). In other words, and generalising, anything that cannot be
incorporated within his standard microeconomic reasoning will be excluded from
economics – that is the world has to fit the theory, the vision, rather than vice-versa,
the very method par excellence for generating the scholars’ PT.16
No wonder old-style Keynesian, Solow, displays extreme distaste for the New
Classical Economics, as expressed and widely cited as follows, Klamer (1984, 146):

Suppose someone sits down where you are sitting right now and announces to me that he
is Napoleon Bonaparte. The last thing I want to do with him is to get involved in
a technical discussion on cavalry tactics at the Battle of Austerlitz. If I do that, I’m getting
tacitly drawn into the game that he is Napoleon Bonaparte.

But his own promotion of the economy as a single production function, and treatment
of technical change as a residual in the 1950s is no less Napoleonic and, indeed,
facilitated further the macro as micro extremes of what was to follow, however much
unpalatable to him as a Keynesian. And for recent Nobel laureate and Chief Economist
at the World Bank, Paul Romer, he rightly complains of the discipline’s17:

(1) Tremendous self-confidence


(2) Unusually monolithic community
(3) Sense of identification with the group akin to identification with a religious faith
or political platform
(4) Strong sense of the boundary between the group and other experts
(5) Disregard for and disinterest in ideas, opinions, and work of experts who are not
part of the group
(6) Tendency to interpret evidence optimistically, to believe exaggerated or incom-
plete statements of results, and to disregard the possibility that the theory might
be wrong.

He experienced and complains of the mainstream’s total contempt for those who
question their dogmas as a lack of loyalty to be punished by being stigmatised. He
forcibly complains of what he calls the post-real (PT?) macroeconomics that ‘the
trouble is not so much that macroeconomists say things that are inconsistent with
the facts. The real trouble is that other economists do not care that the macroecono-
mists do not care about the facts.’18
Yet, is this the same Paul Romer who invented the new growth theory, for which he
won a Nobel Prize, which wasted the discipline for two decades19 and in response to the
question of whether Schumpeter influenced his thinking, confesses, Snowdon and Vane
(2005, 686)20:

No, I can honestly say that it has not. Schumpeter coined some wonderful phrases like
“creative destruction” but I did not read any of Schumpeter’s work when I was creating my
model. As I said, I really worked that model out from a clean sheet of paper. To be honest,
the times when I have gone to try to read Schumpeter I have found it tough going. It is
really hard to tell what guys like Schumpeter are talking about [laughter].

Which leads us to (Blanchard 2008, 1), erstwhile Chief Economist at the IMF, who in
2008, could suggest (emphasis added):
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 9

For a long while after the explosion of macroeconomics in the 1970s, the field looked like
a battlefield. Over time however, largely because facts do not go away, a largely shared vision
both of fluctuations and of methodology has emerged. Not everything is fine. Like all
revolutions, this one has come with the destruction of some knowledge, and suffers from
extremism and herding. None of this deadly however (sic). The state of macro is good.

Subsequently, in 2010, he had the integrity to confess five mea culpas, PTs indeed, in
explaining how the state of macro was no longer good, that: low inflation should be
a primary target of policy; this could be achieved through the single instrument of the
interest rate; fiscal policy was of limited significance; financial regulation was not
a macroeconomic matter; and, with the Great Moderation, continued stability was
more or less guaranteed, Blanchard, Dell’Ariccia, and Paolo (2010). Surely, though,
the issue is not so much that such PTs should be corrected once realism unavoidably
intervenes, but that they could ever have been entertained as ‘good’ in the first instance,
decade, or longer!
Let me, then, whilst on the theme of macro and the state, recall the Conference at the
UK Treasury to which I was invited, after the crisis broke, on the relevance of
Keynesianism, in front of an audience of 200 relatively newly-appointed government
economists (1700 in all). That Keynes was being brought back in, let alone my being
invited, suggested some sort of PT was getting its come-uppance, however temporarily.
The Chief Economist for government opened the proceedings by saying he had two
things to say; first, that nothing within economic theory was of any use to him in
offering policy advice; and, second, nonetheless, he was obliged to present any advice in
its frame of reference. PT rules or, more exactly, ineffective quantitative easing for
a decade in a futile attempt to get the economy moving again, or a successful attempt to
restore finance’s fortunes if not everybody else’s.

5. The state of South Africa, the military and cost-benefit analysis is good?
Different considerations apply in case of South Africa, where in a report commissioned
by President Mandela in 1993,21 I argued that the major constraint on delivering health,
education, electrification and housing was the institutional capacity to deliver but
treating it as a financial constraint would make matters worse. Almost immediately,
the response was to embrace neoliberalism and its dynamic with the disastrous effects
that are not so much being felt as accelerated in terms of lack of growth, other than in
unemployment and inequality. Just a few years later, in a report to the Congress of
South African Trade Unions (COSATU) on industrial policy, I highlighted that the
major issue was whether the developing world’s most sophisticated financial system (it
had spent more than a century funding the extraction of gold) would generate sufficient
finance for industrial and other forms of investment.22 Twenty years later, sorry to
report, that the issue had not been addressed, that South Africa had been investing less
than half that was needed to become a developmental state, and that was just about the
amount of capital that was being exported from the country, much of it illegally
through transfer pricing.23
Was this because the financial system had shrunk and so had failed to undertake its
key mission within the world of PT of mobilising and allocating resources for invest-
ment? Far from it, finance has been the fastest growing sector of the South African
10 B. FINE

economy, now 20% of GDP. This is itself a PT. For it is only relatively recently that
finance has been included in GDP rather than being seen as a transfer, with trading in
(rather than the creation of) risk and financial services (ie taking our money) seen as its
contribution. Go back to the original definition and the PT becomes one in which
finance takes one-quarter of our GDP from us, calls it a service, and has the cheek to
say it has added that quarter to GDP.
Such considerations point once more to the salience of financialisation to our
understanding of contemporary capitalism, legal or otherwise, and the way in which
it has come to dominate global and everyday lives, in extensive but what I have termed
variegated ways across economic and social development, with work on South Africa as
well as pensions, health, water and housing, and much more besides. Not only does PT
economics eschew financialisation (and more long-standing analysis of finance itself)
but, whilst this is the iceberg into which the Titanic discipline has crashed not only
unseen but presumed to be unsinkable, the state of macro is good; this is the mere tip of
the iceberg in terms of the otherwise hidden issues of technological change, global
corporate power, distribution, ethics, interdisciplinarity, and so on.
So the first time I met Nelson Mandela, he asked me what can we do about multi-
national corporations – in the event, in South Africa, it became not how to beat them
but how to financialise, globalise and join them with rich rewards, corrupt or otherwise,
for doing so. The second time I met Mandela, I introduced him to the Chief Executive
of British Airways, who said he could now face down his daughter because his hand had
touched Mandela’s. On that same trip, in the Dorchester, I was minding the Minister of
Trade and Industry, and an employee of British Aerospace burst out that he had built
the local sports centre, so where was his contract. This took me back to my school days
when, in a summer job, at Hawker-Siddeley, I was assigned to the Progress Department,
‘tolkachi’ in the terminology of the Soviet Economy which I studied as a postgraduate –
a room full of operatives trying to make sure spare parts arrived on time to where they
were needed. Significantly, when not making weapons of mass destruction, they were
not making their own slot machines but importing German ones and adding value by
changing the coin mechanism. I worked out on washers they had sufficient supply for
18,000 years. Being a 16-year-old maths geek, I was put on working out a rational policy
for spare stock levels, taking account of cost, use, and storage space, basically to do the
work of the consultant employed for the purpose. But the formula was not the main
issue, it was the social relations of resentment arising out of threat to jobs by rationalis-
ing progress, and need for progress chasers.
Which brings us to the military, and PT (Washington Post-Truth even) in all its
glory. I am not sure if any of you have heard of Daniel Ellsberg. He has a paradox
named after him, an academic economist at the Rand Corporation (basically the CIA’s
research wing and which inspired Arrow on social choice theory to work out US
objectives, and also gave us John Nash and game theory to work out nuclear strategy).
Ellsberg was on the programme, his paradox was that people prefer simple probabilistic
choices to more complex ones, even if they have the same expectations. This got him
into the CIA with access to all documentation, particularly research on the progress and
prospects for the Vietnam War – cannot win, futile to pursue. He was appalled and
leaked the truth, recently made into a film by Steven Spielberg, ‘The Post’ (that’s how
long it takes to get to the truth), in part inspired perhaps as a reaction against Trump.
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 11

Ellsberg was the Julian Assange of his time, famous not least because his psychiatric
records were burgled and released in an attempt to discredit him, the beginning
rumblings of Watergate.24 He came to see little old me in the early seventies at the
Department of Economics, Birkbeck, Gresse Street, with everyone hanging out of their
doors to see him, because his big PT around the Pentagon papers made him question
this known-to-be futile war (and Cold War as research showed the USSR did not want
to conquer the world), with a lean towards explanation in terms of the economic
interests of the Military Industrial Complex, first posited by President Eisenhower,
a former general himself, in his farewell presidential speech of 17 January 1961. He
wanted to discover the truth behind the PT.
And he continues to campaign against the Military Industrial Complex as he sees it,
and the PT wars and military interventions that it inspires. My own ‘war’, engaged on
the picket lines at Battersea Power station, delivering my PhD manuscript to the candle-
lit binder in the 3-day week and power cuts of the Heath government of the early 1970s,
centred on the British coal industry. Ultimately, it led in the mid-1980s, after the
miners’ strike was lost, to pit reviews. During the strike, the pit deputies, in
a separate union to the National Union of Miners (NUM), the National Association
of Colliery Overmen, Deputies, and Shotfirers. (NACODS), threatened to go on strike
because of pit closures. This would have closed all mines as by law the deputies have to
be present during mining for safety reasons. Peter McNestry, the union leader, stayed
with me . . . he left a very large pair of underpants behind. He was far more militant
than his membership and, under pressure and against his will, had to give up the strike
on the condition, granted by Mrs Thatcher, that any mine would not be closed without
consideration of an Independent Judicial Review of its economic and social
consequences.
I was a witness to such a review, calculating the economic and social costs of closure
and presenting evidence on this to an independent judge as arbitrator. During an
interval, there was a question over how much coal was left in the seam and whether
the seam ran horizontal or not, important for ease of extraction. The NUM’s engineer
was dithering over what to say, and his professional reputation, should he prove to be
wrong. Arthur Scargill, NUM President, was very clear . . . This is not about the coal in
the seam; it’s about defeating Mrs Thatcher. Do you think any of their engineers are
going to present the truth? Get out there and say there’s coal.
Be this as it may, my evidence concerned the costs associated with redundancy
payments, the loss of overhead contribution that would be covered if the pit closed, the
lost direct and indirect tax revenues, the multiplier effects in the local community and
beyond, the added costs of unemployment benefit and health-related costs of mental
and physical distress. We won the case – there were few others as the still nationalised
Coal Board nastily offered better redundancy conditions if the workers did not choose
to go to colliery review. But the Coal Board turned around and said, ‘We have
considered the review as legally required but have decided to close anyway.’ No one
expected this when the offer of reviews was made. But the moment had passed. From
one million workers at the time of World War One, 600,000 at end of World War Two,
300,000 as the Scargill disputes began, the industry, that was the most productive in
Europe, has come down to a few thousand. What was true, who told it and who
told PT?
12 B. FINE

Interestingly, the essentially PT accounting to justify pit closures gave rise to a new
field, critical accounting, questioning how accounts are constructed and deployed, and
how they should be deconstructed. A similar story can be told of the Sizewell B nuclear
power public inquiry in which I was a witness on, you have guessed it, the economic
and social costs as well as coal prices.25 It was a PT alternate universe. Now, unlike for
the pit reviews, the coal price was estimated to be going through the roof, to justify
nuclear to displace it. Almost every single assumption favoured nuclear over coal. The
more you questioned these assumptions, the more they were changed but without
affecting the overall decision. The effect of critical evidence, in other words, was only
to strengthen the already-decided answer. And, after a year-long enquiry closed,
Chernobyl happened before the Inspector could report on the accumulated evidence
presented – and he could not consider its implications for safety and cost of safety
because he had, necessarily by virtue of timing, not heard evidence on it!26 Sizewell
went ahead, electricity privatised, and the very same individuals who ran the privatised
industry refused to take on nuclear because it was uneconomic. And currently, for the
(now French, state-owned) UK nuclear programme, we have Chinese funds, to build an
unproven technology (indeed, overrun in costs and timing wherever it has been
attempted) by a French state company that is on the cusp of going bankrupt. Such is
the commitment of the state under the latest phase of neoliberalism to use its own
resources to guarantee private profits of finance and provisioning and to argue private is
better than the public as a result! PT rules, and rules, and then rules again, and
especially in labour markets where we were told, not least by George Stigler, the
Chicago Nobel to micro as Friedman is to macro, that increasing the minimum wage
is bound to decrease employment and anyone who believes otherwise cannot be an
economist. Well, the evidence proved him wrong, and now the profession is more
evenly divided on the matter, with the PT of the traditional proponents depending on
arguing that if you correct for everything that increases employment with the minimum
wage, then employment does fall. Think it through. This is much like the World Bank
(WB) on the East Asian newly industrialised countries (NICs) and the developmental
state. Yes, we agree, there were extensive industrial interventions but these merely did
what the market would have done had the market been working perfectly.
But back with labour markets and human capital theory and the dual notions that
skills derive from something akin to investment, possibly upon the job, and they are
rewarded accordingly. My work on South Africa on its Presidential Labour Market
Commission, on consumer durables and female labour market participation, on equal
pay for women within the UK mining industry and the legal obstacles to achieving it,
on the Labour Plan for Ken Livingstone’s Greater London Council, abolished by Mrs
Thatcher, all suggested otherwise. Labour markets are structured in relation to one
another and internally too.27
Well, I decided not to travel overnight to Cape Town to be there when the Report of
the Commission was presented to the President (a third chance to meet, waived because
I would have needed to fly back the same day to meet my SOAS teaching obligations . . .
by the way, you are the first to hear that I turned down the chance to take South African
citizenship28 and become an economic advisor to Mandela). Two consecutive nights on
the plane, quite apart from global warming. But during the Commission, I did get to
interview the Governor of the Reserve Bank, gratefully inherited from the apartheid era.
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 13

When I asked Chris Stals the reason for high levels of unemployment in South Africa,
he responded that the South African Reserve Bank’s model indicated that real wages
were too high. This led me to ask at what level of real wages would the Bank’s model
give rise to full employment, to which there was no answer (twtwna). Asked if there was
a case for housing finance to be subsidised to generate employment and provide cheap
homes, he responded that this was a microeconomic question but that he would have to
advise government of the negative macroeconomic implications. Asked for his response
to the idea of a subsidy to keep gold mines open, he replied this was a microeconomic
question but that he would have to advise the government of the negative macroeco-
nomic implications. I pointed out that gold at that time contributed 40% of foreign
exchange and this was surely a macroeconomic question, twtwna.
Stals continued in post until 1999. I first encountered him, though, in the early 1990s
at a conference to discuss the post-apartheid economy and its regional and global
prospects. There was a side meeting of the Governors of the Central Banks of 10
southern African countries. They all had one thing in common; they were white,
male and middle-aged. This has now changed and, indeed, his place is now currently
taken by a black SOAS alumnus, as have been Director Generals of Trade, Industry and
Finance, leading figures in privatisation, and Chief Executive of Eskom, the huge public
enterprise electricity corporation. Sorry to say that a SOAS education is not guaranteed
against becoming rich, famous, and climbing one or other of the greasy poles across
government and commerce, if not, sadly as was intended in our student training
programmes, academia.

6. Social capital, the World Bank and all that jazz


Time for my lecture is running short, and I am immodest enough to observe I have
scarcely begun to cover some of the other areas in which I have sought to combat PT or,
some might think, contribute my own. Working on South Africa over the past 30 years
has pulled me into the development field where, inevitably, the scale and scope of PT
purveyed by the WB is mind-boggling. When I came to SOAS I took over teaching all
the theory for the MSc, half the course. For Macro, I tried to make sense of the WB/
IMF rationale for stabilisation and structural adjustment programmes. What I found is
their models allowed for no growth, for instability and, eventually, leading to the
Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs) framing – a model with one labour market
and full employment!29 This essentially precludes consideration of poverty given its two
main sources are unemployment and low wages in employment!
With others at SOAS, in the lead, we have traced the shifting postures of the World
Bank from Washington Consensus to Post Washington Consensus and beyond.30 One
of my own obsessions was social capital, which the WB heavily adopted in the mid-
1990s as the so-called missing link in development and dropped equally rapidly in the
early 2000s as it became more state-friendly (ie having privatised as much as we can, we
now need the state to use its resources to support the private sector in general, and
private finance, in particular, to provide what the state should itself provide). Indeed,
despite its meteoric rise and fall in development, social capital became the missing link
across more or less anything, and its leading proponent, the most cited author across
the social sciences in the 1990s, Robert Putnam, with no apparent evidence, claimed
14 B. FINE

that joining an association was better for your health than giving up smoking. Here is
a partial sampling from social capital and health:

It will improve mental and self-reported health, health at work, life satisfaction and well-
being, and children’s health; and lower risk of violence, accidents, suicide, coronary heart
disease, cancer, teen pregnancy and ‘risky’ and pre-marital sexual activity, fatalism, being
overweight, chances of drug (ab)use (apart from cannabis!) and addiction (but enhance
successful withdrawal), being a depressed mother of young children, low birth weight of
children, excessive alcohol consumption, and so on. Social capital is truly a wonder drug.
Brazilian dental caries. Or talk to a friend or get a dog instead of going to the dentist.

These are the hidden benefits of joining the SOAS Alumni Association . . . go home and
wonder at the improved quality of your teeth.31
In the UK, the NHS undertook a survey of social capital asking whether you could
borrow £10 from a neighbour. Don’t call an ambulance, go next door and borrow some
money. And Blair set-up a social capital unit in Downing Street. It moved lock, stock
and barrel to Cameron’s Big Society Unit, funded the Institute of Governance with
Cabinet Minister, Lord Sainsbury’s money, and privatised itself from Cameron to
become part of the research organisation Nesta, promoting its own nudge unit which
brings us full circle back to the World Bank and its promotion of nudge in the World
Development Report of 2015, with the missing link now being for mayors in developing
countries to share their shower to save water.32
My critique of social capital was not met kindly by the WB but a mole within told me
three things would happen. I would be told to ease off because they were changing;
none of my points would ever be answered; and I would be offered a job to internalise
external criticism. Actually, none of these happened. The leading social capitalist at the
Bank (an erstwhile critic who had been given a job) did eventually agree to debate with
me . . . on condition, we each give in advance three questions for the other. One of his to
me was why did I never publish in mainstream journals. This led me to search the WB
database, let us not forget, the self-proclaimed knowledge bank, for articles by me (sorry
for the vanity). There were none! There was just one reference to me in the whole WB
website – a report that I had been successfully asked to suggest a theme for The Annual
Bank Conference on Development Economics, ABCDE.
This has a story of its own. I had been asked by email to do this as the Bank sought
to answer criticism that it did not canvas widely enough. I suspiciously ignored the
request, until I got another email. I replied asking was this genuine interest in my
thoughts, and not a legitimising exercise, to which the answers were yes and no,
respectively. So, I answered. My suggested theme was turned down, but I also learned,
from moles again, that the then Chief Economist said I should never be invited to
ABCDE! Well, by chance, it was going to be held in Stockholm but the City changed its
mind because of policing problems with demonstrators. And Oslo took it instead. By
chance, the chief economic advisor to the Norwegian Development Agency was a friend
of mine, indeed, I had examined his PhD on Marxist value theory as semiotics. He
invited me to participate (in the panel he was entitled to organise) especially after I told
him I was not allowed to come, and he chose one on ethics and development. So,
Cinderella did go to the ball but did not get to marry the prince. For I was even asked to
submit my paper to the conference proceedings, judiciously dealt with large numbers of
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 15

referees’ comments, only to be told rejected. Damn, another mainstream journal turn-
ing me down.33

7. Economics imperialism and mainstream authoritarian monopoly


In its own fairy-tale way, this indicates that PT is not just about what is said, but who
can say and who controls the saying. This prompts me to move, if briefly, to a number
of inter-related areas in which I have been active – methodology, history of economic
thought, interdisciplinarity and, of course, combining all of these and more, Marxist
political economy.34 For the first two of these, there is much in common – namely,
ignorance and distortion as far as the mainstream is concerned. The commonplace idea
that Adam Smith anticipated General Equilibrium, for example, through his invisible
hand and praise of the market is simply fallacious (Smith was concerned with breaking
down feudal barriers and extending the scope of the market for intra-firm division of
labour aka economies of scale, neither of which appear in general equilibrium to my
knowledge). In general, history of economic thought is ignored and frowned upon as
indicative of an inferior thought that has been surpassed, so much so that its practi-
tioners have mainly abandoned economics altogether and have fled to the history of
science where they can be taken seriously. Similarly, the methodology has been ignored,
and some notion of long-discredited falsifiability is seen totally wrongly as both
legitimate and representative of the physical sciences.
In contrast, interdisciplinarity is different as it is now thriving as never before within
mainstream economics, indicative of the previously mentioned economics imperialism,
critically studied over more than two decades.35 Economics imperialism began seriously
with Gary Becker, his Nobel cites this, in which in its early phase (there are two to come
and build upon his initiatives), all social, non-market phenomena are treated as if
subject to optimising individuals (as well as the market itself). In the classic phrase of
Nobel, public choice, James Buchanan, the choice between war and peace is the same as
between apples and pears. The first phase of economics imperialism gave way, following
the monetarist counter-revolution of the 1970s, to the market imperfection, asymmetric
information revolution most closely associated with Joe Stiglitz, who with Spence and
Akerlof, shared Nobel prizes. As is well known, the emblematic ‘exemplar’ of the new
market imperfections economics is Akerlof’s market for lemons, or second-hand cars.36
Asymmetric information between buyers and sellers means the market is inefficient.
Those wishing to get together to exchange a superior (inferior) car at higher (lower)
price cannot do so since such cars are indistinguishable from one another and so must
sell at the same price. Higher quality cars may be driven from the market at too low
a price, and lower quality cars crowd in at price higher than value. This is inefficient as
such but it is also possible that there will be excess supply (demand) if prices settle high
(low) or absence of markets altogether if no one trusts quality sufficiently. But this has
nothing to do with second-hand cars in particular. The same could happen in any
market. Concerned dealers might group together and offer a warranty scheme, a non-
market, collective solution. By the same token, this is the embryonic form of the state,
culture, habit, institutions, etc. Microeconomic market imperfections are enabled to
explain the non-market as responses to those imperfections with, as mentioned, Akerlof
going on to treat identity as a variable in a utility function (your and others’ utilities
16 B. FINE

become arguments in your utility function – these ties you up in knots as utility
functions can only be constructed in case they are independent of others).
This holds the key to the next, and current, phase of economics imperialism,
characterised by what I have called ‘suspension’, preceding the Global Financial Crisis
(GFC) but accelerated by it. Never mind that the very conceptualisation and construc-
tion of our basis concepts such as utility and production functions depend upon
excluding all sorts of social factors let alone making a thicket of technical assumptions,
let us explain these excluded considerations with utility and production functions,
optimising behaviour and the like but supplemented by whatever other assumptions
and variables we care to incorporate irrespective of consistency with whatever is already
there. So, microeconomics and market imperfections allow more or less any other
economic and social variable to be incorporated on the basis of optimising individuals.
This potential inclusion of variables as a response to market imperfection holds the key
to the current, newer phase of economics imperialism, emerging prior to but acceler-
ated by the GFC.
As a result, the exclusive preoccupation with optimisation can be suspended, but it is
not discarded. It might be combined with other motivations, and other constraints
other than the market. Even where optimisation (especially as utility maximisation) is
abandoned altogether, there is a tendency for it to remain present in the form of what
individuals would do if they or the world in which they live were perfect. Such
suspension enriches the scale and scope of bringing back in interdisciplinarity, allowing
for mixed theories in the formulation of the loosest of models – throw in variables and
estimate, dovetailing with increasing presence of econometrics which allows
a corresponding shift in meaning of model from theory to an equation or six to be
estimated, ideally with large data sets and increasingly sophisticated methods and tests.
In short, economics and economics imperialism in its latest phase of suspension is so
powerful and confident in its core conceptual apparatus that it is able to breach it at will
in extending itself to ever more areas of application. In a sense, it is fake news within
the realm of academia. It also projects itself from an extraordinarily powerful position
of institutional, Americanised strength, over training of PhDs, control of journals,
command of Nobel Prizes, and so on.37
But, equally, matching the overwhelming and even increasing institutional hold of
the mainstream over the discipline, there are striking and gathering intellectual weak-
nesses. The first and most stunningly obvious is incapacity around the Global Financial
Crisis – the inability to explain, even after the event, how it could have
happened. Second is the lack of a coherent world vision, whether Ricardian,
Keynesian or even monetarist that commands general support despite the unanimity
around unquestioned methods, centred on, even if suspended from, its core content.
Third is the inability of economics to explain the economy, the need to draw upon
other social sciences and variables to do so, an implicit acceptance that economics as
such is unfit for the economy without supplementation from the non-economic and the
other social sciences. Fourth, once the mainstream trespasses onto other disciplines,
outside its extreme methods, conceptualisations and assumptions, it exposes itself to
critical alternatives drawn from the other social sciences. Fifth, the systemic and
interpretative aspects of the other social sciences, and the humanities are the least
amenable to economics imperialism although weak assaults are and can be made –
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 17

mainstream economics is extremely uncomfortable with the non-individualistic or what


can be derived from it, not least around issues of power and conflict, and equally
uncomfortable with critical examination of the meaning and reconstruction of concepts
and meanings and their normative content.
The most recent and obvious example of most of these weaknesses is provided by the
previously observed financialisation. But, whilst understandably prominent as
a deficiency of the mainstream, brought to light by the Global Financial Crisis, as
also already mentioned this is merely the tip of the iceberg of a legion of deficiencies
driven even by a suspended methodological individualism – how do we deal with
innovation, distribution, monopolisation, globalisation, neoliberalisation, the exercise
of power, conflicts, their meanings, contextualisation and other determinants?

8. Prospects for alternatives


This allows for a more positive turn in our account, especially where interdisciplinarity
is concerned and through which mainstream economics is exposed by mainstream let
alone radical social science. For it is precisely with its narrow and reduced conceptua-
lisation of the economy that mainstream economics’ weaknesses have their other-
worldly mirror images in other social sciences. Nor is this merely a matter of logic
and differences in interdisciplinary boundaries and inner content. Following a period of
postmodernism, without ever fully discarding its fecund successors (varieties of post-
this and that -isms) over the past 20 years, the social sciences have taken a more
material or realist turn, as reflected in the treatments of neoliberalism and globalisation
and, as already mentioned, financialisation. Attention has turned to how these devel-
opments around neoliberalism, globalisation and, increasingly, financialisation, have
affected everything from systemic functioning to our daily lives of situated individuals
as opposed to those defined by exogenously given utility functions.
The result has been a blossoming of political economy across the social sciences and
a sort of Cold War between it and mainstream economics, in which limited serious
engagements take place other than in the unfulfilled demands of students for the
Rethinking of Economics and its more pluralistic teaching. This is why the formation
of Political Economy associations are so important in bringing together critiques of the
mainstream, its putative interdisciplinarity, and its intolerance of alternatives. And, in
the current economics imperialism era of suspension, we must be mindful of the
seductive charms of what I dub orthodox heterodoxy or even pluralism. So extreme
is the mainstream across so many dimensions, that a simple breach of just one appears
to suffice to (self) label as non-mainstream despite the overwhelming weight of content
remaining not only unchanged but unexamined and taken for granted. It all began with
Stiglitz and his presumed critique of what he dubbed neoclassical economics, as
opposed to what remains his information-theoretic contribution to it.38 But now it
takes many different forms and content, not least with behavioural economics and game
theory, although much more besides, to the fore. Corresponding criticism and search
for, and spread of, different approaches have underpinned my own intellectual motiva-
tion in part for a number of decades, not least in how to sustain and to reproduce
traditions and knowledges of alternatives, with critical knowledge of, and to be turned
18 B. FINE

against, the increasingly intolerant monopoly of the mainstream’s token reliance upon
suspension.39
In this respect, institutionalising alternatives to mainstream economics has faced an
enduring and increasingly difficult problem – how to sustain recognised degrees in
economics (and heterodox research judged as of low quality by narrow and intolerant
mainstream criteria) whilst both covering the mainstream’s increasingly technical,
narrow (and yet woefully inadequate) demands and offering further material across
history of thought, methodology and (genuine) interdisciplinarity, quite apart from
SOAS’s additional demands around specialisation in development and specific devel-
oping countries and regions.40 Within SOAS itself, this issue has been more avoided
than broached by a strategy of sustaining degrees in economics by remaining institu-
tionally separate from other disciplines and departments (once the Department had
been split off from politics in the early 1990s, and Terry Byres as the new head created
its unique character of combining heterodoxy with area studies and development as
well as spawning a separate Department of Development Studies). My own inclination,
however, with some wavering has been different – namely, to sustain independent
degrees in economics within an institutional home that is much broader.
To this end, in a review in 1998, commissioned by the School on its social sciences,
I proposed the creation of an Institute for Social Sciences. As revealed in the centenary
history of the School, this review and others for other disciplines were never intended to
be taken seriously by management even though it had commissioned them.41 They
served more as a subterfuge to allow dissent against management to die down whilst
alternative plans were put in place (possibly colonisation by University College) to
address the enduring financial crises that SOAS suffers as a unique, small institution,
covering something like two-thirds of the world’s population and so thinly spread
across its intellectual responsibilities (quite apart from, at that time, a limited record
of research achievement given its traditional role of training civil servants to rule the
Empire).42
My proposals, though, were fiercely attacked in a series of poems by the (self-
proclaimed, certainly de facto) Bard of SOAS, William Radice, Bengali expert,43 his
interventions reflecting an enduring problem for the institution – that languages and
cultures are deemed to be loss-making but unwilling to change themselves, or anything
elsewhere in the School in case that thin end of a wedge might rebound upon them. My
main response, ‘From Bard to Verse’, a title best read with a Yiddish accent, is
reproduced as an appendix with explanatory notes at https://www.soas.ac.uk/econom
ics/research/workingpapers/file139489.pdf. Subsequent restructurings of the School
continue to leave frustrated my preferred form of situating economics, through opposi-
tions from various quarters, including those internal to the Department itself (fearful of
loss of external status as economics).
Nonetheless, SOAS’s Department of Economics has played a, if not the leading
(international) role, in sustaining and promoting both criticism and critical alternatives,
alongside broader associations and initiatives to sustain and develop these over and
above its own teaching and research programmes. For nearly three decades, SOAS has
disproportionately contributed to the Rethinking, the Reteaching, the decolonisation
and, it should be added, the degendering of the mainstream in pursuit of pluralist,
heterodox political economy. I can be excused for mentioning the International
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 19

Initiative for Promoting Political Economy in particular – iippe.org – now 10 or more


years old, of which I am currently Chair and in which more than 100 SOAS alumni
have actively participated. SOAS alumni have also populated heterodox economics
departments around the country. You and the institution of which you are an alumnus
remain vital to the prospects for political economy, and for a post-PT economics.

Notes
1. Note that research students, and colleagues, have been a rich source of joint research and
collaboration. But, with one exception, apart from referencing publications, I have
refrained from mentioning individuals in what follows despite a huge debt of contribution
and gratitude (hopefully deservedly felt in both directions).
2. I have had the chance on two previous occasions to write about my life as an economist,
see Fine (2001a, 2012a). In the former, I was tickled to realise I was the youngest living
contributor!.
3. In the good old days of hard copy, accessing a PhD thesis required the reader to sign
a form, Fine (1974). Decades after I finished my thesis, I went back to get a copy for
myself and found only one person had ever requested it. Nonetheless, it gave rise to
a stream of publications as such (and beyond in investigating consumer norms, see
below) and exercised my technical skills subsequently to allow them to continue to tick
over and provide some mental exercise and pleasure. See Fine (1975a, 1975b, 1985,
1995, 1996) and Fine and Fine (1974a, 1974b). I even have a technical problem that
I have yet to resolve concerning whether ordinality of individual preference imposes
any constraints on social choice, given utility sum rule, as is the case for cardinal
preferences (e.g. some alternatives cannot come first even though Pareto efficient
because some other, not always the same, alternative dominates contingent on the
choice of interpersonal weights in adding utility)!.
4. For a recent take on social choice theory (as economics imperialism), see Fine (2018a).
5. See http://oecdinsights.org/2011/10/11/comparative-advantage-doing-what-you-do-best
/for example.
6. See Fine (1980, 2003a, 2016a).
7. The articles did ultimately appear as Fine (2002b, 2009).
8. For this work, see Fine (1983a, 1992), Fine et al. (1992a, 1992b, 1992c, 1992d, 1992e, 1993),
Fine and Simister (1995).
9. On the SoP approach, see Fine and Leopold (1993), Fine (2002a, 2013c). It has since been
extended to public sector SoPs, PSSoPs, and to finance and financialisation. See Bayliss,
Fine, and Robertson (2018) and Bayliss et al. (2019), and for a list of contributions around
the Fessud project, fessud.org, see Appendix to Fine (2017a).
10. See Fine (1998a) and Fine, Heasman, and Wright (1996), and NCD Risk Factor
Collaboration (2017) and Lancet Diabetes & Endocrinology Commission (2017).
11. See Fine (2013a).
12. For all work on the coal industry, see Fine (1990). This includes a telling critique of
McCloskey on total factor productivity in the industry at the end of the nineteenth
century. I also taught a course with him when she was a visitor at Birkbeck, then Don
not Deidre.
13. See Fine (1994).
14. See Fine (2010b, 2010c, 2011a, 2011b, 2012b, 2012c, 2012d,, 2014), Bayliss, Fine, and
Robertson (2018) and Bayliss et al. (2019), and other work from fessud.org, listed in
appendix to Fine (2017a).
15. See Dymski (2015) although, unsurprisingly, diluted (suspended, see below) understand-
ings of financialisation have begun to appear within mainstream literature.
16. For the trajectory of mainstream macro, see Fine and Dimakou (2016).
20 B. FINE

17. See Romer (2016).


18. For the arrogance of economists, see Fourcade, Ollion, and Algan (2015).
19. See Fine (2000, 2003b, 2006b).
20. Yet he petulantly concludes in terms of what he perceives will be seen as the stigma
attached to his breaking ranks with orthodoxy:
When the person who says something … is a revered leader of a group, there is a price
associated with open disagreement. This price is lower for me because I am no longer
an academic. I am a practitioner, by which I mean that I want to put useful knowledge
to work. I care little about whether I ever publish again in leading economics journals
or receive any professional honor because neither will be of much help to me in
achieving my goals. As a result, the standard threats … do not apply.
So, the way to get economists to tell the truth is to allow each to establish a new field,
publish in the major journals, become Chief Economist at the World Bank, get a Nobel
Prize, and then not give a damn.
21. MERG (1993). For a full account of the rise and fall of the MERG project, see Padayachee
and van Niekerk (2019).
22. See Fine (1997b) and for a prescient account of the steel industry, Fine (1997c), a report
commissioned because, such was the monopoly pricing on the domestic market, South
Africa was importing fridges made of its own steel at a price lower than its own
manufacturers could buy that steel to make its own fridges.
23. On the developmental state paradigm (and South Africa and illegal capital flight), see
Ashman et al (2010a, 2010b; 2011b), Fine (1999, 2010d, 2010e, 2013b, 2016b), Fine and
Rustomjee (1997), Fine and Pollen (2018) and Fine, Saraswati, and Tavasci (2013). And for
South Africa and financialisation, Ashman, Fine, and Karwowski (2018).
24. See https://therealnews.com/stories/daniel-ellsberg-on-assange-arrest-the-beginning-of-the
-end-for-press-freedom and closing image.
25. See Fine (1983b).
26. This is like a Black Swan event in which you pretend it has not happened rather than
continuing to insist all swans are white. Consider Eugene Fama, leading and continuing
proponent of the efficient market hypothesis, with over one-quarter of a million down-
loads of his academic papers. He continues to deny that bubbles exist or even to know
what they are but is modest enough to confess, ‘We don’t know what causes recessions.
Now I’m not a macroeconomist so I don’t feel bad about that’, https://www.newyorker.
com/news/john-cassidy/interview-with-eugene-fama.
27. See Fine (1998b).
28. It is often assumed I am South African, because of my work but also through confusion
with sociologist Bob Fine (including what might have been some fall out from his being
the first man to bring a restraining order against a woman for sexual harassment). I was
also offered South African citizenship by Joe Slovo, indicative of the height of appreciation
prior to the MERG fall from grace.
29. See Fine (2006a).
30. Fine, Lapavitsas, and Pincus (2001), Fine and Jomo (2006) and Bayliss, Fine, and Van
Waeyenberge (2011).
31. See Fine (2001b, 2010a) and, most recently, Fine and Ortiz (2016).
32. See Fine et al. (2016).
33. For the full story and the paper, see Fine (2004a).
34. I will say no more beyond this footnote about Marxist political economy. My introduction
to Capital, first published as Fine (1975c), is now in its sixth edition, with Alfredo Saad
Filho having come on board as co-author to add some freshness. It has sold more copies
and been translated into more languages than all of my other books put together, Fine and
Saad Filho (2016). My contributions to Marxist political economy have been dedicated to
correcting and developing Marx’s insights and as a coherent body of work against the
misinterpretations of his friends and foes alike, and to apply corresponding analytical
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 21

principles in investigating the shifting contours of accumulation through economic and


social restructuring and reproduction. For recent contributions in this vein, see Fine
(2017b, 2019b). Despite the more than usually, even for me, excessive self-referencing in
this piece justified, or at least apologised for, in light of the occasion, there are other areas
of my work that I scarcely cover or not at all, not least methodology, history of thought,
social policy, industrial policy, the British economy, privatisation, other topics arising out
of critical takes on the mainstream, and many topics in and around ‘development’.
35. Initially, Fine (1997a), in detail Fine and Milonakis (2009) and Milonakis and Fine (2009),
Myrdal and Deutscher prize winners, respectively, and most recently Fine (2019a).
36. For asymmetric information economics as Kuhnian paradigm shift, see Fine (2001c, 2002c,
2004b).
37. As just one index, upon consulting the website of the University of Chicago in 2010,
I found the claim of connections to 25 laureates in economics out of a total of 64 –
compared, for example, with three in literature and sixteen in chemistry but with the latter
two over a period of 108 rather than 40 years, http://www.uchicago.edu/about/accolades/
nobel/ For peace, there is just one connection, to Barack Obama! As we are on criteria, it is
widely acknowledged that Elinor Ostrom is the first, and only, woman to receive the award
(although a political scientist, not an economist) – the only female economist to receive
a Nobel Prize, for peace, is Emily Greene Balch. Otherwise 60% of the economists have
been of US origin, and only four laureates by birth or naturalisation have come from
outside the USA or Western Europe (Arthur Lewis, Leonid Kantorovich, Amartya Sen and
Robert Mundell), with corresponding implications for racial composition.
38. See Fine and Van Waeyenberge (2006).
39. I am acutely conscious that I have had little to say about why mainstream economics
should be so extreme and inappropriate and remain the way it is. Although there are
disagreements over what is the current nature of economics, Fine (2016c, 2019a), its
trajectory and nature are much easier to specify than the reasons for this to which,
institutionally, the Americanisation of the discipline from the 1950s to extreme propor-
tions currently, has much responsibility. By the same token, reform from within and
merely by critical commentary from without are not liable to be effective in exerting major
change rather than reinforcing suspended heterodox orthodoxy. Only when broader social
demands are made upon the discipline is there any chance of major change, in line with
serious challenges to neoliberalism after which our economists will surely follow their own
dictum of responding to incentives.
40. See Fine (2018b).
41. See the centenary history of SOAS, Brown (2016).
42. And, to add insult and injury, the School set-up a new department around finance and
management that was a patent and blatant initiative to create a rival mainstream depart-
ment of economics to the prevailing heterodox department within SOAS itself.
43. Radice’s (2017) own poems have been published, marking SOAS’s centenary, referencing
the poetic debate with me but not including my contributions which I only discovered in
hard copy upon clearing up my office in anticipation of retirement.

Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

References
Ashman, S., B. Fine, and S. Newman. 2010a. “The Crisis in South Africa: Neoliberalism,
Financialization and Uneven and Combined Development.” In The Crisis This Time,
Socialist Register, 2011, edited by L. Panitch, et al., 174–195. London: Merlin Press.
22 B. FINE

Ashman, S., B. Fine, and S. Newman. 2010b. “The Developmental State and Post-Liberation
South Africa.” In Testing Democracy: Which Way Is South Africa Going? Institute for
a Democratic South Africa, edited by N. Misra-Dexter and J. February, 23–45. Cape Town:
ABC Press.
Ashman, S., B. Fine, and E. Karwowski. 2018. “Introduction to the Special Section
‘Financialization in South Africa’.” Competition & Change 22 (4): 383–387. doi:10.1177/
1024529418791762.
Ashman, S., B. Fine, and S. Newman. 2011. “Amnesty International?: The Nature, Scale and
Impact of Capital Flight from South Africa.” Journal of Southern African Studies 37 (1): 7–25.
doi:10.1080/03057070.2011.555155.
Bayliss, K., B. Fine, and E. Van Waeyenberge, (eds). 2011. The Political Economy of Development:
The World Bank, Neoliberalism and Development Research. London: Pluto Press.
Bayliss, K., B. Fine, and M. Robertson, (eds). 2018. Material Cultures of Financialisation. London:
Routledge.
Bayliss, K., B. Fine, M. Robertson, and A. Saad Filho. 2019. Neoliberalism, Financialisation and
Welfare: The Political Economy of Social Provision in the UK. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
forthcoming.
Blanchard, O. 2008. “The State of Macro.” NBER Working Paper, no 14259. http://www.nber.
org/papers/w14259.pdf
Blanchard, O., G. Dell’Ariccia, and P. Paolo 2010. “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy.” IMF
Staff Position Note. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1003.pdf doi: 10.5089/
9781455224982.004.A001.
Brown, I. 2016. The School of Oriental and African Studies Imperial Training and the Expansion
of Learning. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Christophers, B. 2013. Banking across Boundaries: Placing Finance in Capitalism. Chichester:
Wiley-Blackwell.
Christophers, B. 2018. The New Enclosure: The Appropriation of Public Land in Neoliberal
Britain. London: Verso.
Dymski, G. 2015. “How to Engage with the Global Crisis: The Shape of Jazz to Come.”
International Initiative for Promoting Political Economy. Accessed 29 December 2017. http://
iippe.org/wp/wp-content/uploads/2015/10/Dymski-IIPPE-keynote-as-presented.pdf
Fine, B. 1974. “Individual Decisions and Social Choice, London School of Economics.” Phd
thesis, University of London, supervised by Amartya Sen, examined by Frank Hahn.
Fine, B. 1975a. “A Note on Interpersonal Aggregation and Partial Comparability.” Econometrica
43 (1): 169–172. doi:10.2307/1913422.
Fine, B. 1975b. “Individual Liberalism in a Paretian Society.” Journal of Political Economy 83 (6):
82–96. doi:10.1086/260397.
Fine, B. 1975c. Marx’s ‘Capital’. London: Macmillan. Reprinted in 1977, 1979, 1981 and 1982,
revised edition, 1984. Spanish, Italian and Greek editions published in 1976 and reprinted in
1980. Dutch edition revised and published in 1980, Korean edition published in 1985,
Japanese edition, 1989, third edition, 1989, fourth edition, with co-author Alfredo Saad-
Filho, with Pluto Press in 2003, with Korean (2004) Turkish (2006) and Indian (2010) editions,
fifth edition with Pluto in 2010, and Norwegian edition, 2009, and Korean edition, 2010,
Chinese edition, Guizhou Educational Publishing House, 2011, Danish edition, in
Copenhagen: Solidaritet, 2011, Spanish edition, in Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura, 2013,
and 2018, French edition, Raisons d’Agir, 2013, Turkish edition, Yordam, 2012, sixth edition,
Pluto Press, 2016, Chinese edition, Beijing: Renmin University Press, forthcoming, Portuguese
edition, Presença 2018.
Fine, B. 1980. Economic Theory and Ideology. London: Edward Arnold.
Fine, B. 1983a. “The Order of Acquisition of Consumer Durables: A Social Choice Theoretic
Approach.” Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation 4: 239–248. doi:10.1016/0167-
2681(83)90009-4.
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 23

Fine, B. 1983b. “The Future of Coal Prices.” Proof of Evidence to the Sizewell ‘B’ Power
Station Public Inquiry, Centre for Energy Studies, Polytechnic of the South Bank, CES/P/2,
October.
Fine, B. 1985. “A Note on the Measurement of Inequality and Interpersonal Comparability.”
Social Choice and Welfare 1 (4): 273–277. doi:10.1007/BF00649262.
Fine, B. 1990. The Coal Question: Political Economy and Industrial Change from the Nineteenth
Century to the Present Day. London: Routledge. reproduced as Routledge Revival, 2013.
Fine, B. 1992. Women’s Employment and the Capitalist Family. London: Routledge. reprinted as
Routledge Revival, 2011.
Fine, B. 1994. “Coal, Diamonds and Oil: Towards a Comparative Theory of Mining.” Review of
Political Economy 6 (3): 279–302. doi:10.1080/09538259400000040.
Fine, B. 1995. “On the Relationship between True Preference and Actual Choice.” Social Choice
and Welfare 12 (4): 353–361. doi:10.1007/BF00186279.
Fine, B. 1996. “Reconciling Interpersonal Comparability and the Intensity of Preference for the
Utility Sum Rule.” Social Choice and Welfare 13 (3): 319–325. doi:10.1007/BF00179235.
Fine, B. 1997a. “The New Revolution in Economics.” Capital and Class, no. 61: 143–148.
doi:10.1177/030981689706100107.
Fine, B. 1997b. “Industrial Policy and South Africa: A Strategic View.” NIEP Occasional Paper
Series, no 5. Johannesburg: National Institute for Economic Policy.
Fine, B. 1997c. “Vertical Relations in the South African Steel Industry.” NIEP Occasional Paper
Series, no 13. Johannesburg: National Institute for Economic Policy, originally a report for
NUMSA Investment Company.
Fine, B. 1998a. The Political Economy of Diet, Health and Food Policy. London: Routledge.
Fine, B. 1998b. Labour Market Theory: A Constructive Reassessment. London: Routledge. rep-
rinted in paperback, 2010.
Fine, B. 1999. “The Developmental State Is Dead - Long Live Social Capital?” Development and
Change 30 (1): 1–19. reproduced in D. Moore (ed) The World Bank: Development, Poverty,
Hegemony, Scotsville: University of KwaZulu-Natal Press, with afterword, 2007, pp. 121–44.
doi:10.1111/dech.1999.30.issue-1.
Fine, B. 2000. “Endogenous Growth Theory: A Critical Assessment.” Cambridge Journal of
Economics 24 (2): 245–265. doi:10.1093/cje/24.2.245.
Fine, B. 2001a. Entry in A Biographical Dictionary of Dissenting Economists, second ed. Aldershot:
Edward Elgar. 172–179. edited by P. Arestis and M. Sawyer.
Fine, B. 2001b. Social Capital versus Social Theory: Political Economy and Social Science at the
Turn of the Millennium. London: Routledge. Turkish edition, Yordam Kitabevi: Istanbul.
Fine, B. 2001c. “Economics Imperialism as Kuhnian Revolution?” International Papers in
Political Economy 8(2): 1–58. shortened version in Praksis, no 3, 2001, pp. 154–184, in
Turkish.
Fine, B. 2002a. The World of Consumption: The Cultural and Material Revisited. London:
Routledge.
Fine, B. 2002b. “Economic Imperialism: A View from the Periphery.” Review of Radical Political
Economics 34 (2): 187–201.
Fine, B. 2002c. “Economics Imperialism and the New Development Economics as Kuhnian
Paradigm Shift.” World Development 30 (12): 2057–2070. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00122-5.
Fine, B. 2003a. “Capital Theory.” In The Elgar Companion to Post Keynesian Economics, edited by
J. King, 51–57. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. second edition, 2012, pp. 68–74.
Fine, B. 2003b. “New Growth Theory.” In Rethinking Development Economics, edited by H.-
J. Chang, 201–217. London: Anthem Press.
Fine, B. 2004a. “Economics and Ethics: Amartya Sen as Point of Departure.” World Bank
ABCDE Conference. Oslo. June 2002. published in The New School Economic Review, vol
1, no 1, Fall, pp. 151–62. http://www.newschooljournal.com/files/NSER01/95-104.pdf
Fine, B. 2004b. “Economics Imperialism as Kuhnian Revolution.” In The Rise of the Market,
edited by P. Arestis and M. Sawyer, 107–144. Camberley: Edward Elgar.
24 B. FINE

Fine, B. 2006a. “Financial Programming and the IMF.” In The New Development Economics:
After the Washington Consensus, edited by B. Fine and K. S. Jomo, 87–100. Delhi: Tulika.
London: Zed Press.
Fine, B. 2006b. “New Growth Theory: More Problem than Solution.” In The New Development
Economics: After the Washington Consensus, edited by B. Fine and K. S. Jomo, 68–86. Delhi:
Tulika. and London: Zed Press.
Fine, B. 2009. “The Economics of Identity and the Identity of Economics?” Cambridge Journal of
Economics 33 (2): 175–191. doi:10.1093/cje/ben036.
Fine, B. 2010a. Theories of Social Capital: Researchers Behaving Badly. London: Pluto Press.
Fine, B. 2010b. “Locating Financialisation.” Historical Materialism 18 (2): 97–116. doi:10.1163/
156920610X512453.
Fine, B. 2010c. “Neo-Liberalism as Financialisation.” In Transitions to Neoliberalism in Middle-
Income Countries: Policy Dilemmas, Economic Crises, edited by A. Saad-Filho and G. Yalman,
11–23, London: Mass Resistance, Routledge.
Fine, B. 2010d. “Can South Africa Be a Developmental State?” In Constructing a Democratic
Developmental State in South Africa: Potentials and Challenges, edited by O. Edigheji, 169–182.
Cape Town: Human Sciences Research Council Press.
Fine, B. 2010e. “The Developmental State?” In Zuma’s Own Goal: Losing South Africa’s ‘War on
Poverty’, edited by B. Maharaj, A. Desai, and P. Bond, 101–124. Trenton, NJ: Africa World
Press.
Fine, B. 2011a. “Beyond Financialisation.” In Economic Crisis and Greece, for the Greek Scientific
Association of Political Economy, edited by A. Vlachou, N. Theocarakis, and D. Milonakis,
19–36. Athens: Gutenberg, (in Greek).
Fine, B. 2011b. “Locating the Developmental State and Industrial and Social Policy after the
Crisis.” UNCTAD, The Least Developed Countries Report 2011: The Potential Role of South-
South Cooperation for Inclusive and Sustainable Development, Background Paper No. 3. http://
www.unctad.org/Sections/ldc_dir/docs/ldcr2011_Fine_en.pdf
Fine, B. 2012a. “Being Radical or Radical Being?” Review of Radical Political Economics 44 (1):
100–106. doi:10.1177/0486613411423890.
Fine, B. 2012b. “Financialisation and Social Policy.” In Global Crisis and Transformative Social
Change, edited by P. Utting, S. Razavi, and R. Buchholz, 103–122. London: Palgrave
MacMillan.
Fine, B. 2012c. “La Financiarisation En Perspective.” Actuel Marx (51). 73–85. in French,
translation of “Beyond Financialisation”, in A.Vlachou, N. Theocarakis and D. Milonakis
(eds), Economic Crisis and Greece, for the Greek Scientific Association of Political
Economy, Athens: Gutenberg, 2011 (in Greek). doi:10.3917/amx.051.0073.
Fine, B. 2012d. “Neo-Liberalism in Retrospect? – It’s Financialisation, Stupid.” In Developmental
Politics in Transition: The Neoliberal Era and Beyond, edited by B. Fine, K.-S. Chang, and
L. Weiss, 51–69. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.
Fine, B. 2013a. “Economics: Unfit for Purpose.” Review of Social Economy LXXI (3): 373–389.
shorter version of “Economics - Unfit for Purpose: The Director’s Cut”, SOAS Department of
Economics Working Paper Series, No. 176, 2013. doi:10.1080/00346764.2013.799969.
Fine, B. 2013b. “Beyond the Developmental State.” African Communist (186): 40–54.
Fine, B. 2013c. “Consumption Matters.” Ephemera 13 (2): 217–248.
Fine, B. 2014. “Financialisation from a Marxist Perspective.” International Journal of Political
Economy 42 (4): 47–66. doi:10.2753/IJP0891-1916420403.
Fine, B. 2016a. Microeconomics: A Critical Companion. London: Pluto Press.
Fine, B. 2016b. “Across Developmental State and Social Compacting: The Peculiar Case of South
Africa.” ISER Working Paper No. 2016/1. Grahamstown: Institute of Social and Economic
Research, Rhodes University. https://www.ru.ac.za/media/rhodesuniversity/content/iser/docu
ments/ISER%20Working%20Paper%20No.%202016.01.pdf
Fine, B. 2016c. “Neoclassical Economics: An Elephant Is Not a Chimera but Is a Chimera Real?.”
In What Is This ‘School’ Called Neoclassical Economics?: Debating the Origins, Meaning and
Significance, edited by J. Morgan, 180–199. London: Routledge.
INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 25

Fine, B. 2017a. “A Note Towards an Approach Towards Social Reproduction.” Unpublished


manuscript. http://iippe.org/wp/wp-content/uploads/2017/01/sroverviewben.pdf
Fine, B. 2017b. “Neither Equilibrium as Such nor as Abstraction: Debating Fred Moseley’s
Transformation.” International Journal of Political Economy 46 (1): 22–28. doi:10.1080/
08911916.2017.1310470.
Fine, B., and G. Pollen. 2018. “The Developmental State Paradigm in the Age of
Financialisation.” In Handbook on Development and Social Change, edited by M. Hyland
and R. Munck, 211–227. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Fine, B. 2018a. “Collective Choice and Social Welfare: Economics Imperialism in Action
and Inaction.” Ethics and Social Welfare 12 (4): 393–399. doi:10.1080/
17496535.2018.1554883.
Fine, B. 2018b. “In and against Orthodoxy: Teaching Economics in the Neoliberal Era.” In
Advancing Pluralism in Teaching Economics, edited by S. Decker, W. Elsner, and S. Flechtner,
78–94. London: Routledge.
Fine, B. 2019a. “Economics and Interdisciplinarity: One Step Forward, N Steps Back?”. Revista
Crítica De Ciências Sociais forthcoming.
Fine, B. 2019b. From Agronomy to Rent in Marx’s Political Economy. mimeo.
Fine, B., and A. Saad Filho. 2016. Marx’s Capital. sixth ed. London: Pluto Press.
Fine, B., C. Lapavitsas, and J. Pincus, (eds). 2001. Development Policy in the Twenty-First
Century: Beyond the Post-Washington Consensus. London: Routledge.
Fine, B., D. Johnson, A. Santos, and E. Van Waeyenberge. 2016. “Nudging or Fudging: The
World Development Report 2015.” Development and Change 47 (4): 640–663. doi:10.1111/
dech.12240.
Fine, B., and D. Milonakis. 2009. From Economics Imperialism to Freakonomics: The Shifting
Boundaries between Economics and Other Social Sciences. London: Routledge. Turkish edition,
Ankara: Heretik Publishing, forthcoming.
Fine, B., and E. Leopold. 1993. The World of Consumption. London: Routledge.
Fine, B., and E. Van Waeyenberge. 2006. “Correcting Stiglitz: From Information to Power in the
World of Development.” Socialist Register, London: Merlin Press, Vol. 42, 146–168.
Fine, B., and J. Ortiz 2016. “Social Capital: From the Gringo’s Tale to the Colombian Reality.”
SOAS Department of Economics Working Paper Series, no 195.
Fine, B., J. Saraswati, and D. Tavasci, (eds). 2013. Beyond the Developmental State: Industrial
Policy into the 21st Century. London: Pluto Press.
Fine, B., and J. Simister. 1995. “Consumption Durables: Exploring the Order of Acquisition.”
Applied Economics 27 (11): 1049–1057. doi:10.1080/00036849500000088.
Fine, B., and K. Fine. 1974a. “Social Choice and Individual Ranking, Part I.” Review of Economic
Studies 41 (3): 303–322. doi:10.2307/2296751.
Fine, B., and K. Fine. 1974b. “Social Choice and Individual Ranking, Part II.” Review of Economic
Studies 41 (4): 459–475. doi:10.2307/2296697.
Fine, B., and K. S. Jomo, (eds). 2006. The New Development Economics: After the Washington
Consensus. Delhi: Tulika. and London: Zed Press.
Fine, B., M. Heasman, and J. Wright. 1996. Consumption in the Age of Affluence: The World of
Food. London: Routledge.
Fine, B., N. Foster, J. Simister, and J. Wright 1992a. “Consumption Norms, Diffusion and the
Video/Microwave Syndrome.” SOAS Discussion Paper, no 19.
Fine, B., N. Foster, J. Simister, and J. Wright 1992b. “Access to Phones and Democracy in
Personal Communication: Myth or Reality?” SOAS Discussion Paper, no 20.
Fine, B., N. Foster, J. Simister, and J. Wright 1992c. “Who Owns and Who Wants to Own a Car?
an Empirical Analysis.” SOAS Discussion Paper, no 21.
Fine, B., N. Foster, J. Simister, and J. Wright 1992d. “Consumption Norms: A Definition and an
Empirical Investigation of How They Have Changed, 1975–1990.” SOAS Discussion Paper, no
22.
Fine, B., N. Foster, J. Simister, and J. Wright 1992e. “Consumption Norms for Durables:
Evidence from the General Household Survey.” SOAS Discussion Paper, no 23.
26 B. FINE

Fine, B., N. Foster, J. Simister, and J. Wright. 1993. “Consumption Norms, Trickle-Down and the
Video/Microwave Syndrome.” International Review of Applied Economics 7 (2): 123–143.
doi:10.1080/758530143.
Fine, B., and O. Dimakou. 2016. Macroeconomics: A Critical Companion. London: Pluto Press.
Fine, B., and Z. Rustomjee. 1997. The Political Economy of South Africa: From Minerals-Energy
Complex to Industrialisation. London: Hurst. 278. and Johannesburg: Wits University Press,
pp. ix and.
Fourcade, M., E. Ollion, and Y. Algan. 2015. “The Superiority of Economists.” Journal of
Economic Perspectives 29 (1): 89–114. doi:10.1257/jep.29.1.89.
Klamer, A. 1984. Conversations with Economists. Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Allanheld.
Lancet Diabetes & Endocrinology Commission. 2017. “Diabetes in sub-Saharan Africa: From
Clinical Care to Health Policy.” The Lancet Diabetes & Endocrinology 5 (8): 622–667.
doi:10.1016/S2213-8587(17)30181-X.
Lucas, R. 1981. Studies in Business Cycle Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
MERG. 1993. Making Democracy Work: A Framework for Macroeconomic Policy in South Africa.
Cape Town: CDS. 1994, also New York: Oxford University Press, 1994, and translated into
isiZulu as Ukwenza Intando Yeningi Isebenze, Durban: Community Law Centre, 1993.
Milonakis, D., and B. Fine. 2009. From Political Economy to Economics: Method, the Social and
the Historical in the Evolution of Economic Theory. London: Routledge.
NCD Risk Factor Collaboration. 2017. “Worldwide Trends in Body-Mass Index, Underweight,
Overweight, and Obesity from 1975 to 2016: A Pooled Analysis of 2416 Population-Based
Measurement Studies in 128·9 Million Children, Adolescents, and Adults.” Lancet 390:
2627–2642. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(17)32129-3.
Padayachee, V., and R. van Niekerk. 2019. Shadows of Liberation: ANC Economic and Social
Policy from African Claims (1943) to GEAR (1996). Johannesburg: Wits University Press.
Radice, W. 2017. Poeta Scholasticus: SOAS Verses & Poems. London: SOAS.
Romer, P. 2016. “The Trouble with Macroeconomics.” As the Commons Memorial Lecture of
the Omicron Delta Epsilon Society, forthcoming in, The American Economist. Accessed 5
January 2016. https://paulromer.net/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/WP-Trouble.pdf
Samuelson, P. 1966. “A Summing Up.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 80 (4): 568–583.
doi:10.2307/1882916.
Snowdon, B., and H. Vane. 2005. Modern Macroeconomics: Its Origins, Development and Current
State. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

You might also like