Winseck, Dwayne PDF
Winseck, Dwayne PDF
4(2), 73–114
© The Author 2016
http://www.polecom.org
Abstract
Within communication studies, the political economy of communication (PEC)
approach is typically seen to be the sole preserve of Marxist scholars, with origins in the
late 20th century. Such a view, however, obscures an older, trans-Atlantic political
economy tradition forged by Europe and North American scholars who made
communications media central objects of their analyses in the late-19th and early-20th
centuries. This earlier tradition was imported into communication studies through the
halfway house of sociology, mostly after the turn of the 20th century, thereby thoroughly
entangling the intellectual history of communication studies with that of political
economy from the beginning. Moreover, the formative years of the field were never the
barren ‘administrative wasteland’ often thought. Indeed, combined with the research
done beyond the field’s borders by economists, business historians, legal and regulatory
scholars, etc. throughout the 20th Century, a wealth of underused resources is close-to-
hand that can help us to reimagine and reconstruct what we mean by the PEC traditions
today. This article starts to recover these neglected elements, and the contributions of
the institutionalist and Cultural Industries schools especially. It closes with a
survey of recent PEC research and a handful of provocations that contemporary
researchers might explore: (1) in an evermore internet- and mobile wireless-centric
world, bandwidth is king, not content; (2) subscriber fees are now the economic
base of the media not advertising, by roughly a 3:1 ratio; (3) rather than seeing
media as a ‘unified system’, developments vary greatly across media: some are
growing fast, others stagnating, and yet others appear to be in decline; (4) people
create, consume and share a lot of media outside the market; and (5) contra
neoliberal mythology, the role of the state remains vital: as regulator, a counter to
market power, investor and in terms of surveillance.
Winseck 74
Within communication and media studies, the political economy of communication (PEC) approach
is typically seen to be the exclusive preserve of Marxist scholars, with origins in the latter half of
the 20th century. This article, however, argues that such a view obscures the PEC’s much older and
more diverse backstory, including the institutionalist and Cultural Industries schools that are still
important today.
That the political economy of communication is typically seen in the ways just suggested is
clearly apparent. One of the most prolific contemporary writers in this tradition, Christian Fuchs
(2012), for example, declares that “the political economy of the media is Marxist Political
Economy”. Eileen Meehan and Janet Wasko (2013) also state that “scholars who identify as
political economists of the media generally work within Marxist traditions” (40). Jonathan Hardy
(2014) similarly highlights the Marxist core of the PEC and links its origins to the New Left of the
1960s (189-190). While Vincent Mosco’s (2009) The Political Economy of Communication surveys
a broad range of approaches to political economy, ultimately he suggests that when it comes to
communication and media studies, the main lines of development are variations on Marxist political
economy.
Critics of the field agree. Timothy Haven, Amanda Lotz and Serra Tinic (2009), for example,
chastise “several generations of academics who have maintained an unreconstructed Marxist
theoretical framework” (238). Lisa Holt and Lisa Perren (2009) similarly charge that “the North
American strand of critical political economy is reductive, simplistic, and too economistic” (8-9).
Stuart Cunningham, Terry Flew and Adam Swift (2015) say much the same thing. Further examples
could be piled like so many leaves in Autumn, but the point is clear.
These views have become entrenched over generations of adversarial debates, form the
Administrative/Critical encounter of the 1940s to the recurring tensions in the last three-and-a-half
decades between Cultural Studies and Creative and Media Industries Studies scholars on the one
side, and Critical PEC scholars on the other. Many “new materialist”, “infrastructure studies” and
“platform studies” scholars do not mention political economy at all, seemingly wary of tainting
their “new materialism” with a whiff of the “old” Marxist stuff (e.g. Gillespie, Boczkowski & Foot,
2014: 7; Gitelman, 2006: 8). The rough consensus on all sides is that the PEC emerged from the
work of Dallas Smyth and Herbert Schiller in tandem with the rise of New Left politics in the
1960s, although some include Harold Adam Innis’ Empire and Communication as well as The Bias
of Communication (1950 and 1951, respectively). Theodor Adorno’s chapter on the Culture
Industry in The Dialectic of the Enlightenment (1947/2002) is also regarded as a founding text.
A closer look, however, reveals that an incipient approach to the PEC emerged in the late-19th
and early-20th centuries, long before Smythe, Schiller, Adorno or Innis. This could be seen in the
work of European and North American scholars such as Karl Knies, Karl Bücher, Albert Schäffle,
Ferdinand Tönnies, Charles Horton Cooley, Edward Ross, Albion Small, Franklin Giddings,
Richard Ely, Thorstein Veblen, amongst others. Indeed, arising during the ‘progressive era’ as it is
called in the US, and the ‘age of social reform’ in Europe (Sklar, 1988; Rodgers, 2000), these
scholars saw extended networks of communication and transportation, and the greater mobility of
capital, goods, people, knowledge, news and culture they enabled, as central to the then-new age of
capitalist modernity.
In short, communications and media had already become significant objects of inquiry within a
loose, cross-Atlantic political economy tradition - a formation that predated the differentiation of
the social science disciplines in the early to mid-20th century – and the emergence of PEC in its
contemporary Marxist form. The earlier tradition was imported into communication studies through
Winseck 75
the halfway house of sociology, mostly after the turn of the 20th century. To put it boldly, political
economy is the mother of communication and media studies, if we look back far enough and
carefully enough across the disciplines.
Moreover, many others who worked beyond the field’s disciplinary boundaries - economists,
legal and regulatory scholars, business historians and others - dealt directly with issues of
monopoly, anti-trust and regulation in many communication and media industries (including news
wire services, telecommunications, film, broadcasting, and computing). Their efforts bequeath to us
a wealth of resources that can help us to reimagine and reconstruct what we mean by the political
economy of communication.
The article concludes by surveying contemporary work being done by political economy
scholars. I will attend to the broad structures and finer details of the telecoms, internet and media
industries, while proposing some themes around which contemporary research might be fruitfully
advanced. These can be listed as follows:
1. In an ever more internet- and mobile wireless-centric world, the media
infrastructure industries [1] are now the centre of gravity around which the rest of
the world and ‘the media’ revolves. Bandwidth is king, not content, and our
research priorities should reflect this reality (Odylzko, 2001);
2. Subscription fees and the pay-per model have become the main source of revenue
in the media economy compared to advertising by roughly a 3:1 ratio. They
constitute the ‘economic base’ of the media. This has enormous implications for
what we should be focusing on and how we should think about the ‘audience
commodity’.
3. While a heightened state of flux affects all media, the dynamics of such processes
vary greatly - some media are growing quickly, others are stagnating and yet
others (mostly advertising-based) may be in terminal decline (Miege, 2011; Noam,
2016; Preston and Rogers, 2012).
4. People create, consume and share a lot of media outside the market (Benkler,
2006; Garnham, 1990; Lobato and Thomas, 2015; Miege, 1989).
5. Against the discourses of ‘neoliberalism’ and ‘deregulation’, the role of the state
remains vital. Such is demonstrated by the growth of telecoms and media
regulators worldwide since 1990 (from 14 to 166), the increased state investment
in broadband internet infrastructure, the responses to high levels of concentration
in some media markets, and the spread of mass internet surveillance.
Unlike Smith, Marx (1867/1978) depicted capitalism as a revolutionary new kind of society
driven by the universalization of commodity exchange and the “creation of a world market” (163).
Improvements in communications expanded the reach of markets while deepening the division of
labour, but, most importantly, they served as the information infrastructure of the capitalist mode of
production (Calhoun, 1992). As Marx (1867/1972) put it:
[c]apital by its nature drives beyond every spatial barrier. Thus the creation of the
physical conditions of exchange -- of the means of communication and transport—the
annihilation of space by time -- becomes an extraordinary necessity for it . . . . [T]he
production of cheap means of communication and transport is a condition for
production based on capital, and promoted by it for that reason (459, emphasis added).
While communication scholars typically stress the links between the development of
communications networks and the practices of politics, war and imperialism (Headrick, 1991),
Marx saw communications infrastructures as developing along the lines of commerce and trade.
These infrastructures were primarily shaped by capital investment, mainly in the North Atlantic
region. They were developed least, and last, within the underdeveloped territories of the British,
European and Japanese empires. This occurred only after much state aid (not just by one
‘government’ but several in cooperation with one another). Private enterprise operated in relation to
these institutional settings. The British-based Eastern Telegraph Company, for example, laid a
series of submarine telegraph cables around the African continent only in the 1880s and 1890s --
decades after it had done so in the more economically developed areas of the world economy
(Topik and Wells, 2012: 84-97; Winseck and Pike, 2007).
As the dynamic processes of capitalism unfolded, Marx saw the everyday life of people as
becoming enmeshed in distant events, more specialized, more subject to constant change and more
segmented. Greater social differentiation, not homogeneity (as encapsulated by the ‘mass society’)
was the result. In contrast to 2000 years of thinking since Aristotle that saw economies as embedded
within society and directed for multiple purposes (e.g. production for self-needs; for others with
whom one shares a bond of love, kinship or proximity; and for impersonal exchange via markets),
Marx saw capitalism as an end unto itself to which all else was subordinated, including people’s
lives (labour). Capitalist societies are based on conflict, not harmony, between those who push to
expand the market against those who resist the subordination of the whole world to economic
forces. Conflict is generated also between social groups over the control of resources. In Marx’s
view, the accumulation of wealth confers power, while efforts to conserve both can be used to deter
technological, economic, political and cultural changes that might threaten the status quo.
Capitalism, however, is an extraordinarily dynamic system. By incessantly revolutionizing the
forces of production (technology), space and time are annihilated as barriers to capitalism’s
expansion and a class’s given place in the world will ultimately be destroyed (‘all that is solid melts
into air’) (Calhoun, 1992; Schumpeter, 1943/1996).
About the rise of ‘big business’ Marx offered both general and specific insights. He highlighted,
for example, the rise of the joint stock company, the large capitalization (concentration) of
individual firms, and the consolidation (centralization) of industries and markets. He also
commented on the development of national and international wholesale news-wire services like
Reuters, Havas, Wolff, and the Associated Press. He described their development in the Grundrisse
as follows:
Winseck 77
. . . institutions emerge whereby each individual can acquire information about the
activity of all others and attempt to adjust his own accordingly, e.g. lists of current
prices, rates of exchange, interconnections between those active in commerce through
the mails, telegraphs etc. (the means of communication of course grow at the same
time) (Marx, 1867/1972: 99).
This observation also implies a critique of mainstream economists’ assumption that buyers and
sellers ‘possess an encyclopedic knowledge of commodities’ (perfect knowledge). If everyone had
‘perfect knowledge’, why would such services even exist? This was the first inkling of a persistent
problem in economic theory that future economists would come back to time and again, as we will
see. More than this, however, specialized news services are recursively implicated in economic
processes as well, given their influence on readers’ perceptions (and thus their actions). Information
does not just reflect markets, but helps to constitute them. As Lloyds of London, a giant
international maritime insurance firm, stated a few decades after Marx, “telegraphs and cables
increase the information component of business transactions and provide businesses with
knowledge about markets before they enter them” (Britain, 1899: 156, italics added).
Marx developed his critique of the political economy of capitalism while working as a highly
respected journalist from the 1840s to the 1860s. For example, he edited the Rheinische Zeitung
newspaper while studying political economy in France. He was also a regular contributor to the
New York Daily Tribune, one of the largest-circulation dailies in the US. Marx also valued the
liberal theory of the free press, but his own experience taught him that newspaper publishers,
business interests, and governments routinely intervened in the work of journalists to influence
public opinion. Those lessons appear to inform the passage in The German Ideology where Marx
and Engels famously state:
. . . The ideas of the ruling class are in every epoch the ruling ideas, i.e. the class
which is the ruling material force of society, is at the same time its ruling intellectual
force. The class which has the means of material production at its disposal, has control
at the same time over the means of mental production, so that thereby, generally
speaking, the ideas of those who lack the means of mental production are subject to it
(1846/1932: 64-65).
At the time Marx was writing - the mid-19th century - the forces of political reform and revolution
were spreading across Europe. In those battles, governments, capitalists, conservatives, liberals, and
elites of all kinds feared and loathed the political forces bubbling up from below and bent on
changing the world. And they spared no energy in counteracting (suppressing) those forces. Liberal
guarantees of a free press, free personal correspondence over the wires and through the mails, and
the allied right of privacy (including the use of secret code) were delimited in practice.
Governments, however, monitored and censored telegraphs and the press for reasons of national
security, public order and moral decency. They anchored their authority to do so in international
telecommunications law with the constitution of the Austro-German Telegraph Union (established
1850) and the West European Telegraph Union (1855). After those two entities merged, the
International Telecommunications Union (1865) was formed. Similar threats to liberal guarantees
persist to this day (Koskenniemi, 2002).
Few PEC scholars still adhere to the dominant-ideology thesis of The German Ideology.
Although the idea that powerful interests use the media to achieve their goals is undeniable, in both
Marx’s time and today, the notion that the media are little more than the playthings of those who
Winseck 78
own them is too crude. Evidence of editorial meddling is anecdotal (even if not infrequent) rather
than systematic. The concept of a dominant ideology ignores the fact that media content can be
created that runs counter to the perceived interests of media owners, governments or business. It is
also unclear whether capitalism requires the kind of ‘cultural glue’ that the concept of a dominant
ideology entails (Abercrombie, Hills and Turner, 1980, Thompson, 1990). Media are sites of
contested meaning (between dominant, negotiated and oppositional readings, to use Stuart Hall’s
terms), rather than just tools of power. The focus on ruling-class ideology marginalizes analyses of
the media as objects of economic and institutional analysis. To the extent that the PEC scholars
reflect this tendency - in line with the emphasis in communication studies generally - they give
excessive privilege to ‘the text’ and to questions about meaning at the expense of other pressing
analytical concerns.
Crucially, the structure of media ownership that lent support to the ‘dominant ideology thesis’
when Marx was writing has changed. In the mid-19th Century, newspaper and book publishers were
mostly individuals (media moguls). The media mogul, however, has been steadily cut down to size
since, replaced by shareholders who provide capital in return for a cut of the profits, while hired
expert managers and editors run daily operations (Murdock, 1982; Garnham, 1990). By 1984, only
a third of media companies in the US were owner-controlled. By 2009, the proportion had fallen to
25 percent. The trend is global, even if it varies from place to place and from media to media. Of
course, there are major exceptions to the rule, such as Rupert Murdoch (News Corp), John Malone
(Liberty Media), Brian Roberts (Comcast), Sumner Redstone (CBS and Viacom), Larry Page,
Sergei Brin and Eric Schmitt (Google/Alphabet), Mark Zuckerberg (Facebook) and Robin Li
(Baidu). The trend still stands, however. The interests of shareholders, expert managers and editors
tend to be more diffuse, cross-cutting, and aligned with the capitalist system generally (in contrast
to the older tendency whereby powerful individuals used the media they owned to advance their
own ideological agendas) (Murdock, 1982; Noam, 2009: 8; Noam, 2016: 1200-1201).
For these reasons and more, most Marxist political economists have spurned the dominant
ideology thesis for decades (eg Garnham, 1990; Golding and Murdock, 2005; Murdock; 1982).
Critics of PEC that still lob the instrumentalist charge in spite of such realities are being dishonest
and acting in bad faith (see chapter 2 in Cunningham, Flew and Swift, 2015) [2].
emphasis added). The Americans went abroad to study with political economists and economic
historians such as Albert Schäffle, Karl Knies, Karl Bücher, Ferdinand Tönnies and Gabriele Tarde.
They brought what they learned back to North America and into sociology. The new discipline
thereby gained its independence from economics. In this cross-Atlantic traffic of scholars and ideas,
sociology arose out of European approaches to political economy, and early versions of sociology
put the study of communication at the centre of attention (Cooley, 1910; Hardt, 2001; Peters and
Pooley, 2012: 403; Rodgers, 2000; Simonson, 2012; Young, 2009: 92-93).
In the US, these ideas initially took root in economics departments and were well represented in
the American Economic Association (AEA). Richard T. Ely, a founding member and early
president of the AEA, and a professor of political economy at the University of Wisconsin-
Madison, had also been a student of Karl Knies at the University of Heidelberg. Ely, in his capacity
as the president of the AEA, helped sociology slowly gain its autonomy from economics in the
early decades of the 20th century. Ely and Ross were also colleagues at the University of
Wisconsin-Madison; the latter’s student, Albion Small, became a key force in the development of
sociology and communication research. In fact, Small, Giddings, Cooley and Ross played lead roles
in establishing the first separate sociology departments at Chicago (1894), Columbia (1924),
Michigan (1929) and Wisconsin (1929). Each of these became influential centres of early
communication research.
While some of these figures contributed to the early conceptual groundwork for communication
studies and institutionalizing sociology within the US, it is less well-known that they self-identified
as political economists and were trained as such. In other words, they are the first PEC scholars, and
their work predates not only the formalization of the Marxist PEC, but also communication and
media studies itself as a separate field of inquiry. While it is simplistic to categorize them under a
single label, in this disparate group of individuals one finds the nucleus of the institutionalist
approach to political economy.
A common focus for this early generation of political economy scholars was the development of
national and international postal and telegraph systems, railways, low-cost printing, and the
telephone. These innovations had all helped to enlarge the sphere of commerce, social interaction,
and human experience, while potentially freeing people’s minds of the parochialism found in small
groups and localities (Calhoun, 1992; Hardt, 2001; Sklansky, 2000: 102). As Cooley observed, just
as the “the railroad had transported Americans into an economy of abundance and interdependence;
the communications revolution of the nineteenth century promised no less than ‘the expansion of
human nature itself’” (cited in Sklansky, 2000: 102-103). Likewise, Bücher stressed how the advent
of national postal, railway, and telegraph systems had underpinned German economic and social
development as well as the growth of newswire services and daily newspapers. In North America
and Europe alike, corporations of unprecedented size, reach and capitalization built, owned and
operated the large technical networks (systems) that facilitated the flow of messages, intelligence,
and money. Effectively, they controlled the central conduits for the lifeblood of economy and
society. This was the age of AT&T, Cable & Wireless, Marconi, RCA, Siemens and Western
Union, and the complex technological systems they built lasted for decades, and even a half-century
or more. They exemplified the centralization of ownership in the hands of well-capitalized and
professionally managed firms alongside parallel efforts to avoid ‘ruinous competition’ (Veblen,
1921: 8-13; Danielian, 1939; Schumpeter, 1943/1996). An underlying concern in all of this was that
of the crisis of control. Society had lost influence over these enterprises and the technological
systems they had built, while governments struggled for at least a half-century to develop an
Winseck 80
adequate response (Beniger, 1989; Chandler and Cortada, 2003; John, 2010; Kahn, 1971/1988;
Melody, 1987; Polanyi, 1957/1996; Sklar, 1988).
There is a tendency in the existing literature to focus on the forces of monopoly, geopolitics,
territory, states and nationalistic views of technology and culture. However, this downplays the role
played by business and market forces, the technical details of the media, the informal media
economy and the contribution of media audiences (users) to the development of the ‘industrial
media era’ (Gitelman, 2006; John, 2010; John and Silberstein-Loeb, 2016; Lobato and Thomas,
2015; Stamm, 2011; Winseck and Pike, 2007). To the extent that competition is examined, it is too
often treated as merely a prelude to consolidation. The ‘anti-monopoly’ voices that challenged this
drift of affairs are too often cast as belonging mostly to populist and agrarian movements. However,
the anti-monopoly creed actually appealed to a much wider cross-section of interests, including
early PEC scholars. In fact, it was a mainstay of liberal and laissez-fair political economy in the US
and Europe during the progressive era/age of social reform (John, 2010; Sklar, 1988; Rodgers,
2000). Later, institutionists who analyzed the political economy of the communication industries -
as regulated utilities, common carriers, and the main information infrastructures of industrial
capitalism during the 19th and 20th centuries - such as William Melody, Harold Trebing and Alfred
Kahn, were staunchly anti-monopoly but not in the least populist (see further below).
Competition in telephony, for example, did not arise primarily from small, rural outfits after
Bell’s telephone patents expired in 1893 as conventional wisdom holds. The real competition
occurred between the soon-to-be AT&T and Western Union a decade-and-a-half earlier in New
York, Boston, Chicago and Montreal. In the process, both corporations threw vast sums of money at
the leading engineers of their time – Thomas Edison, Elisha Gray, and Alexander Graham Bell.
Together, they churned out a cluster of cutting-edge technological innovations that came to shape
the communication and entertainment industries well into the 20th century. These were: the
quadraplex technology that doubled the speed of telegraphs; the telephone; the phonograph; and
cinematography equipment. As Richard John (2010) observes, all these innovations arose out of the
odd conjunction of an anti-monopoly political economy and strong intellectual property protections
(156-164).
Instead of continuing their cutthroat competition, however, Western Union and the backers of
the soon-to-be AT&T agreed to wind down their rivalry in order to face a common enemy: Jay
Gould, the infamous ‘robber baron’ who was seeking to acquire both firms. On account of their
truce in late 1879, all of Western Union’s telephone patents and municipal exchanges were given to
Bell in return for annual royalties and pledges to stay out of one another’s markets. Thereafter, the
two fields were divided. In Europe, however, a different trend emerged: telegraphs and telephones
were typically combined under state-owned Post Telegraph and Telephone administrations, thereby
revealing a key lesson in political economy: the same technologies in various capitalist societies
will generate different institutional arrangements and outcomes in each case (John, 2010: 160-170;
Wallsten, 2005).
Competition in and between different ‘communication carrier industries’ - such as the telegraph
and telephone, and wired and wireless technologies - drove technological innovation across the
media. The heated rivalry between Western Union and AT&T, for example, led to fundamental
advances in telegraph and telephone technology, and to institutionalization of the industrial research
lab (Edison labs - Menlo Park). That enabled the growth of the recorded music, movies and parts of
the broadcasting industries after this ‘goliath versus goliath’ battle subsided. It should be
acknowledged that the ‘end use’ of each of these ‘new media’ was only established after being in
Winseck 81
the hands of ‘users’ [3]. As a result of such processes, the entertainment industries in the Anglo-
European world took off after the 1880s, and in Argentina, Brazil and India over the next two
decades (Bakker, 2008; Gitelman, 2006; John, 2010; Parthasarathi, 2005; Silberstein-Loeb, 2008;
Stamm, 2011; Winseck and Pike, 2007).
AT&T’s role in the development of the broadcasting and the film industries in the US was huge.
The company single-handedly rewired the movie business for sound in the late 1920s and early
1930s. It left radio broadcasting, however, because of inter-corporate agreements between itself and
others (e.g. General Electric, RCA, Westinghouse) in the mid-1920s. The communications field was
thereby carved up into areas of mutual exclusivity (with the government’s blessing). A&T then
exited the movie industry at the end of the 1930s in the face of threats of anti-trust litigation
(Danelian, 1939; Wasko, 1981). In sum, yes, there was a long march from ‘methodless enthusiasm’
and ‘ruinous competition’ to ‘consolidation’, as R. L. Thompson (1947) states in Wiring a
Continent, but the line from one end to the other was long, messy and more contested than he and
many others asserted. Moreover, ‘market segmentation’ meant that consolidation was never
complete, and the US government’s communications policy - and that of Canada, the UK and others
- kept things that way for much of the rest of the 20th Century.
While consolidation often occurred within specific communications sectors, business and
governments supported market segmentation for a variety of reasons. Business interests did so
because they wanted to dull the sharp edges of ‘ruinous competition’ [4]. Governments did so to
constrain large corporations’ capacity to use their market power to influence markets within and
across different industries in order to “block private accumulations of power and protect to
democratic government” (Hofstadter, 1965: 188-200). Protecting competition was also seen as a
good thing because it spurred fundamental innovations in communications (Levin, 1969).
Consequently, the communications field was divided up into four largely separate silos: telecoms,
broadcasting, print and, a few decades later, computing (Adams, 1955; Babe, 1990; Barnouw, 1976;
Kahn, 1971/1988; John, 2010: 168-170). These are the origins of ‘media divergence’.
During these formative years of the ‘industrial media age’, circa 1900-1940, those who owned
the means of dissemination generally stayed out of the media content industries; some newspaper
and theatre owners invested in commercial radio where it was permitted (Australia, Canada, Latin
America, the US, for example). Overall, the interrelated culture industries – film, music, radio,
television, and news – developed in close relation to the state and post, telegraph and telephone
systems, but operated independently. How technologies, markets and the state interact to shape the
development and arrangement of communications media in any given time or place is a central task
of the institutionalist approach (Babe, 1990; John, 2010; Kahn, 1971/1988; Melody, 1987; Miege,
1989; Stamm, 2011).
Early institutional PE scholars such as Karl Bücher and Edward Ross carefully chronicled the
rise of the press as a capitalist enterprise on both sides of the Atlantic. Bücher, for example
described the commercial press in Germany as a giant “capitalistic enterprise, a sort of news-factory
within which a great number of people . . . are employed on wage, under a single administration, at
very specialized work” (quoted in Hardt, 2001: 90). In the US, Ross (1910) [5] pinpointed “three
economic developments in the field of newspaper publishing” that were fundamentally changing
the ownership, financing, structure and function of the press (303). As he put it:
. . . the editor who uses his paper to air his prejudices, satisfy his grudges, and serve
his private ambitions, is going out . . . . The necessary plant is so costly, and the
Associated Press franchise is so expensive, that the daily newspaper in the big city has
Winseck 82
become a capitalistic enterprise. . . . This drifting of ultimate control into the hands of
men with business motives is what is known as ‘the commercialization of the press’
(303).
Leading up to the time he wrote, advertising revenue had soared from less than half of all revenue at
a typical big city newspaper to between two-thirds and 90% over a thirty-year period. The “role of
journalism as a cornerstone of liberty and democracy was becoming a mere convenience of
commerce” (Ross, 1910: 304-305). Similar processes took place in Canada (Sotiron, 1997: 4-7), but
only decades later than in the US or Germany. Greater reliance on advertising revenue and the need
for higher levels of capitalization also led to the “subordination of newspapers to other enterprises”,
Ross observed (1910, 305). This broad characterization also anticipated Theodor Adorno’s claim
decades later that the whole ‘Culture Industry’ was positioned in this way. Ferdinand Tönnies
encouraged his contemporaries to take “the press as a capitalistic enterprise” fully into account in
studies of public opinion, and cited Ross’s work as the basis for doing so (cited in Hardt, 2001:
123).
By the early-20th Century, government intervention in communications, media, and information
markets had become extensive and routine. Governments allocated rights to private enterprise to use
scarce public resources like streets, sewers, spectrum and utility poles, for example. They
extensively subsidized some of the means of communication, such as the Post Office in the US (and
elsewhere). This was the cornerstone of media and information policies explicitly designed to
cultivate a vibrant universe of social correspondence and a ‘free press’. Outside North America,
governments also owned telegraph, telephone, wireless, radio and television services in some
provinces/states and municipalities in Canada, the U.S, UK, France, Denmark and Sweden. While
technology and economics were obviously key factors in each case, politics was decisive, and
developments varied greatly from one place to the next because of that fact (Starr, 2004; John,
2010; Wallsten, 2005).
Governments also expanded and remade copyright and intellectual property laws to help bring
about new forms of informational property. Indeed, the old physicalist regime of property rooted in
the mutually exclusive possession of tangible things (e.g. land and other physical resources) that
had held sway since the 17th Century [6] slowly ceded to the bundle of rights view formalized by
US legal scholar Wesley Hohlfeld. In the 1920s and 1930s, this “dephysicalized”, ‘bundle of rights’
model saw property as a cluster of competing claims to value from ‘material property’ and
intangible things like goodwill, patents, information and news (Boyle, 1996: 73; Vandevelde, 1980:
333-345).
In the US, it was not until 1918 that the Supreme Court accepted that news was a form of ‘quasi-
property’ (in the International News Service versus the Associated Press case) [7]. Ironically, the
court drew on the Marxist labour theory of value to achieve this result, arguing that while the thing
itself - ‘news’ - hardly fitted the model of property, the amount of journalistic labour expended plus
the capital and machinery dedicated to making the news merited treating it this way. Justice Warren
Brandeis warned, however, that superimposing the legal container of property over top of the news
could constrict its circulation within the body politic. The idea of property could end up swallowing
up the whole world as the courts were pressed to recognize every new source of value as property
(Boyle, 1996; Tworek, 2016; Vandevelde, 1980).
Similarly, while governments did not recognize a property right to spectrum, once commercial
radio was accepted the spectrum licenses they issued soon became de facto property. Their value
was reflected in the price of buying and selling broadcasting stations, [8] as Thomas Streeter’s
(1996) Selling the Air recounts. Thus, as information and communication resources increased in
Winseck 83
value, the law of property swung in behind to bolster the trend (Babe, 1995; Boyle, 1996; Melody,
1987; Vandevelde, 1980).
Governments also regulated market power, wholesale and retail prices for telecoms services,
network interconnection agreements, and technical standards. Over a fifty-year period, they
constructed an entirely new legal and regulatory edifice for the telecoms and media industries.
Crucial concepts like common carriage that had been developed in common law for centuries were
institutionalized. States intervened extensively to secure the economic base of other public goods as
well such as libraries and education. The record of these efforts still stands as an underused trove of
resources for researchers (Blondheim, 2004; John, 2010; Kahn, 1971/1988; Streeter, 1996).
Of course, governments also promoted trade and fought wars. Free trade as general policy
became the basis for developing submarine telegraph cables for the UK and US. They were
extended around the world from the late-1860s, with major boom periods in the 1870s and 1880s,
and then again after the 1920s. Marconi and Telefunken - the German wireless company - set up
their own branch plants in the US and other countries before the war as well. Indeed, the world was
more open to foreign investment, and companies less closely tied to national interests, than is often
assumed. An ‘iron triangle’ of information power – the surveillance of message flows, censorship
(blocking traffic and cutting cables) and propaganda -- was imposed in WWI but then mostly
dismantled afterwards [9]. Marconi’s radio assets were taken over by the military and its patents
pooled and divided amongst American telecoms and electronics companies to create the Radio
Corporation of America. The Wilson Administration tried to formalize the free flow of information
principle after WWI as part of its bid to restore the belle époche of liberal
internationalism/imperialism that had existed before the War, but several of the big US
communications companies hated the idea (e.g. RCA, the Commercial Cable Company, All
Americas Cable Company). As most European governments and Japan opposed it as well, the idea
was stillborn (Rogers, 1918; Winseck and Pike, 2007: ch. 8).
In sum, the late 19th and early 20th centuries saw essential elements of the industrial information
age (Benkler, 2006), the control revolution (Beniger, 1989) and the ideology of corporate liberalism
(Sklar, 1988; Streeter, 1996) put into place. With each expansion of the market and technology,
countervailing pressures arose to keep them under human (social) control. Karl Polanyi (1957/1996)
called this the “double movement”. States and markets became forever intertwined as a result
(Lindblom, 1977). New communications media held forth the prospect of enlarging the realm of
mental imagination and social intercourse so as to bring personal life into line with the enlarged
scale of the modern world. Whether anything like that would have been enabled by the then current
arrangements of ‘‘business”, as Veblen (1921) understood the term, was an open question
(Calhoun, 1992; Cooley, 1910; Tonnies, 1887/1955). Such prospects, however, were not very good
in any case. As Walter Lippmann (1920) noted in his classic, Liberty and the News, the biggest
factor limiting the flow of international correspondence and news was the high cost of telegraph and
news wire services (3).
Here we have many familiar leitmotifs of the PEC, and they were there at the founding of
communication studies. They tend to be missed in the exclusively Marxist focus the field has taken,
but they are worthy works deserving of equal recognition within the PEC canon. In this early era, it
was not Marxist PEC that was leading the charge but institutionalists. They took an inductive,
empirical, mid-range theoretical approach to the issues (some say they were ‘merely descriptive’).
Their terms of critique were usually liberal and reformist, but occasionally quite radical, as in the
case of Thorstein Veblen. Their politics aside, one thing is clear: all of these thinkers contributed to
Winseck 84
the ongoing development of the PEC. How did these early versions of PEC get forgotten? Crucially,
after World War I, the transatlantic intellectual exchange dried up, and methodological nationalism
prevailed (Beck, 2005; Rodgers, 2000). Sociology’s newly gained separate institutional status also
cut against the interdisciplinary grain of early PEC work, as did administrative communications
research from the 1940s.
While Adorno’s arguments resonate with Ross, Bücher, Cooley and Tönnies’ focus on the
industrialization of culture, he does not mention them. His thesis was also curiously separate from
much else that was taking place when he wrote. The ‘monopoly question’ was indeed a problem,
but not in the abstract way Adorno talked about in the ‘Culture Industry’. The question played out
in pitched battles through the courts and amongst economists and legal scholars.
Like Adorno, C. Wright Mills also thought that the Marxist concept of ideology was passé. In
his view, to the extent ideology does exist, it functions as a kind of cultural glue that binds together
elites so they can see the world in similar ways (Abercrombie, Hill and Turner, 1980; Thompson,
1990). Generally speaking, however, capitalism does not need cultural consensus to maintain itself
over time. Conflict, not consensus, is the order of the day. Mills, however, did think that public
opinion was still important, and agreed with Katz and Lazarsfeld’s (1955) Personal Influence study
that it had not been steam-rolled over by the mass media. He did, however, argue that Katz and
Lazarsfeld’s view of influence wrongly equated the power of ‘personal opinion leaders’
(individuals) with that of ‘media sources’ (institutions). He also argued that effective public opinion
demanded a certain set of conditions:
. . . (1) Virtually as many people express opinions as receive them. (2) . . . [T]here is a
chance to immediately and effectively answer back any opinion expressed in public.
Opinion formed by such discussion (3) readily finds an outlet in effective action, even
against – if necessary – the prevailing system of authority. And (4) authoritative
institutions do not penetrate the public, which is more or less autonomous in its
operations (Mills, 1956: 326).
None of these conditions were close to being met, in Mills’ view. The US communications media
did not amplify ‘the people’s voice’ - that is, the public conversation –-but rather stood arrayed
against the American public as a one-way channel between the few and the many.
Mills’ critical theory of the conditions for ‘effective’ public opinion prefigures Jurgen
Habermas’ The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere (1962) and the two volume Theory
of Communicative Action (1987). Both books are animated by the concern that the liberal model of
the public sphere and rational communication has been eroded by commercial forces. There is no
longer the capacity to generate the kinds of public discourse and culture that will sustain modern
democracies. Like Mills, Habermas never believed that public opinion had been neutered, just
neglected, manipulated or squandered. Thus, twenty years after The Power Elite, he cites Mills (and
Katz and Lazarsfeld) approvingly to make just that point: “the independent weight of everyday
communication in relation to mass communication has been confirmed again and again”
(Habermas, 1987: 435). Yet, for both Habermas and Mills, the key point is that people can talk all
they want (free speech), and they do, but the real problem is, who will listen? Mills and Habermas
also share the idea that ‘systems of power’ are no longer intelligible to people and have grown
impervious to their input. To use Mills’ terms, ‘authoritative institutions’ have also ‘penetrate[d] the
public’. Habermas critiques how the ‘systems world’ –technology, markets and the state – and the
penetrative powers of ‘instrumental rationality’ have colonized the lifeworld and eroded the powers
of communicative rationality. The critique of communication and power they offer marks a further
step away from the ‘dominant ideology’ thesis [10]. Again, both of them (and Katz, Lazarsfeld and
Merton, but each in their own way) continued to see the power of communication, reason and
public opinion as essential to keeping the ‘culture of democracy’ alive.
Winseck 86
blocking their entry into emerging markets. In later cases, there is a concern to promote investment
in new information infrastructures as well as diversity in new computing and information services.
Another priority was to restrict telephone companies’ ability to leverage their monopoly position in
ways that could stifle the independent development of these new fields. By the 1950s, these choices
were already being animated by visions of ‘wired cities’ and the integration of computing and
electronics into all corners of society. Such visions come after Adorno’s Culture Industry thesis; he
can hardly be criticized for failing to ‘predict the future’. Nevertheless, that none of the early legal
cases nor any inkling of what is to come figure in his account suggests that the Culture Industry
thesis was not well grounded empirically.
The steady flow of such cases fueled debates amongst economists and in law schools concerning
the ‘monopoly question’ and, in particular, the ‘new’ Sherman anti-trust law. Conservative
economists argued that expansive interpretations of anti-trust law belied hostility to ‘big business’
and they sought to roll back the tide. Schumpeter (1943/1996), for one, argued that limited
monopolistic competition between large, well-capitalized firms was the new normal. This was
nothing to be worried about. Such an arrangement was the most efficient means of creating wealth
(i.e. a rising tide raises all boats). Major incumbents were kept on their toes by the constant threat of
competition. In any case, monopolistic competition was transitory. Existing technologies and modes
of economic organization would be swept away by a whole new cluster of technologies, businesses
and institutions - a process he called “creative destruction” (83). Schumpeter did not care much
about wealth distribution or how long it might take for existing market concentration to give way to
more competition. He also ridiculed democratic principles. Indeed, Schumpeter’s antipathy toward
democracy entailed fascistic and pro-Hitler sympathies. This uglier side has been left unspoken by
those who approvingly cite his views on creative destruction and innovation in our field, especially
within the creative industries school (see Cunningham, Flew and Swift, 2015). This one-sided
uptake of Schumpeter fetishizes technology and markets without considering the implications of his
views for the public interest and political process.
Alfred Kahn (1988), in contrast, rejected the carte blanche condemnation of anti-trust laws, and
the do-nothing approach to monopolies that Schumpeter counselled. For Kahn, such anti-trust laws
applied mainly to basic infrastructure industries – such as telecoms, transportation, electricity, water
and sewers. They tended to share economic and technical characteristics that made them proper
targets of such regulation in the public interest. Infrastructure industries were characterized by
large, complex technical systems that required high levels of capital investment, strong path
dependencies that tied new technologies to past investments and high levels of concentration. They
were the substrate upon which economy and society generally relied. Regulators had to be wary,
however, that the pursuit of anti-trust policies did not enter deep political waters, or encourage
capture by the industries they oversaw. To avoid the perils of ‘politicization’, anti-trust initiatives
had to stick to basic economic principles and expertise rather than pursuing political values. That
the state and market were inextricably linked, however, was not surprising to Kahn (1988). By the
mid-1930s, Kahn agued, the US government could regulate industry pretty much as it pleased, so
long as it had a clear legal basis from Congress to do so (7-8). Ultimately, in Kahn’s vision,
economics and regulatory expertise trumped politics. As time passed, Kahn became even more
skeptical about the capacity of regulation to solve economic problems, and more of a defender of
the market.
Walter Adams (1954), in contrast, fully endorsed the anti-trust rulings, and supported the need
to deal with the politics head on. Over and against the critics of anti-trust, Adams believed that the
Winseck 88
regulators were confronting the realities of market concentration and vertical integration at a time
when industrial conglomerates were carving out ever-bigger places for themselves across the
economy and society. What critics really wanted, Adams asserted, was to eliminate the obstacles
that curtailed the ability of corporate interests to do as they pleased. In contrast to Kahn, who
thought that the use of anti-trust law could lead to the politicization of the economy, Adams insisted
that economics could not be disentangled from politics. While the goals of anti-trust were indeed
about economics (i.e. to promote economic efficiency, competition and consumer welfare), they
were also necessarily political (i.e. to prevent the private accumulation of power and protect
democratic government). On this view, anti-trust laws, and economic decisions more generally,
unavoidably anticipate a view of what the proper relationship between markets, politics and society
should be. For Adams, unlike Kahn, it was the responsibility of economists to deal with that reality
honestly and to the best of their ability, rather than trying to deflect attention from it, or to pretend
that somehow economics could be cleansed of its political content.
engage in concerted efforts to systematically measure, catalogue and assign an economic value to
‘knowledge workers’ in the ‘information economy’ (relative to the national GDP). By the 1950s,
economists were busy defining, counting, cataloguing and making the place of information within
the economy visible not just to better understand the role it played but also to bring about the
conditions that had long been held in theory but never achieved in practice: perfect
information/knowledge as the basis of the information economy/society (Babe, 1995).
All of these efforts embodied a broader message: change the structure of information available
in a society, and society itself changes. What had been a minor footnote for Marx was now a key
determinant in the evolution of society, at least in some quarters. Babe (1995) argued that to
appreciate these realities, economists would have to choose between force fitting
information/communication into the limiting and unrealistic precepts of their worn-out economic
models or accept that a realistic account required the wholesale transformation of economics into
the political economy of communication. This implied an audacious turning of the tables that would
put communication studies at the top of the intellectual pecking order while bringing the ‘master
discipline’ of economics down a notch or two (of course nothing of the kind ever happened).
If changes in the information environment can change the structure of firms, markets and
society, perhaps they also play a pivotal role in the destiny of civilizations? This is one way to think
about Harold Innis’ Empire and Communication (1950) and The Bias of Communication (1951).
Later chapters in both books follow Ross, Bücher and Adorno by chronicling the rise of the press
and radio as capitalist enterprises, although their works are not cited. He does cite others in the
preface to Empire and Communications, however, who are part of the story told here: Thorstein
Veblen, Frank Knight, George Herbert Mead and Robert Park. They were all part of the Anglo-
Germanic intellectual traditions outlined previously and were faculty members at the University of
Chicago, where Innis completed his Ph.D. Unlike Cooley, Small, Knies, Bücher and others, who
were guardedly optimistic about the potential of communications to reconcile human experience
with the enlarged scale and accelerated pace of modern societies. Innis offered a pessimistic view.
Later chapters in The Bias of Communication and Empire and Communication draw out the
implications that monopolies of knowledge rooted in control of the dominant means of
communication might have for civilizations. For Innis, monopolies of knowledge coalesce around
specific media, conferring power upon those who control them against those whose power is
anchored elsewhere. They are never secure, however, and are subject to pressure from rival (new)
media - from newspapers to radio, orality to print. Industrialization of the press, for example,
greatly magnified the outlay of capital needed to launch and operate a newspaper. This led to
consolidation within the industry and sharply increased the number of copies produced -- all at
much lower prices for each copy. The chain of newspaper production reshaped the economic
geography of entire countries, as well, with entirely new company towns in French-speaking parts
of Canada built up around pulp and paper mills whose sole raison d’être was to feed the voracious
appetite of the New York and Chicago presses.
In tandem with the fast growth of advertising subsidies, the daily press became more affordable
and the size of the reading public grew, although none of this was necessarily a good thing, Innis
thought. Electronic communications had further accelerated the speed with which news travelled,
adding to the frenetic feel of industrial society. This tendency worked against the settlement of
conflict, and triggered the recurrence of industrial scale conflict in in the 20th Century (Innis, 1950:
203-217). Innis was disturbed by these trends and worried about the rise of the American Empire,
with its aggressive, militarist foreign policy governed by experts and cut loose from the influence of
Winseck 90
public opinion. What Schumpeter celebrated, Innis feared, i.e. rule by experts, or technocracy. Like
Mills and Habermas, Innis saw the exercise of power cut free from ‘rational public opinion’ as a
central difficulty for capitalist democracies. However, unlike them he was not optimistic about the
ongoing vitality of democracy.
Perhaps Innis’ best-known idea is that different media have different economic and technical
characteristics. Media, in his view, are not neutral channels through which messages pass
unaffected but rather unique environments that privilege certain kinds of knowledge and
communicative interactions over others. Innis (1951) called this the bias of communication [13].
Those systems (or environments), in turn, are the media in which economies, societies and people’s
experience unfold - subtly shaped by such environmental conditions all the while. In other words,
‘the medium is the message’, as his protégé, Marshall McLuhan later stated. The following passage
below helps to illustrate this point:
. . . [T]he use of a medium of communication over a long period will to some extent
determine the character of knowledge to be communicated and suggest that its
pervasive influence will eventually create a civilization in which life and flexibility
will become exceedingly difficult to maintain and that the advantages of a new
medium will become such as to lead to the emergence of a new civilization (34).
Once again, the idea that communications media are not simply tools for the dissemination of
information arises. Like Marx, Coase, Hayek, Machlup and Knight, Innis emphasizes how they
react back on and shape economic and social life. Like them, he rejects the idea of perfect
knowledge, seeing ‘monopolies of knowledge’ instead. Thus, while economics generally had gone
beyond innocent views of information, it is only the institutionalists like Innis and Veblen, and their
brethren, who connected their reconceptualization of the role of information and knowledge in the
economy (and society) to the critique of power. The Marxist PEC scholars followed later (Babe,
1995; Melody, 1987).
Schiller set out to document the emergence of the telecommunications, media, and information
industries as big business, and the policies and politics that shaped their rise. They investigated the
allocation of scarce public resources, such as spectrum for radio and television, and the links
between these industries and other centers of business, government, and military power.
The “central tendency” of communications and ICTs, as Vincent Mosco (2009) later put it, “is
to deepen and expand the capitalist system” (120). The function of the media in this context is not
political, cultural or ideological but commercial. Indeed, the main role of advertising-based media is
to reconcile mass production with mass consumption and to sell audiences (the ‘audience
commodity’) to advertisers. The main determinant of people’s access to media and information,
Schiller (1989) asserted, was not citizens’ right to know or to communicate -- as theories of the free
press and democracy presuppose -- but the ability to pay. And not all audiences are worth the same.
They are sorted into categories of economic value based on income, race, gender, age and location,
as later researchers argued in more detail (Gandy, 1993). Facebook audiences are a contemporary
example that illustrates the point. In 2015, each Facebook user in North America was worth $2.60
per month. In Europe, a Facebook user was valued at $.90, in Asia $.34, while in Africa and the rest
of the world, the average revenue per user (APRU) was just $.24 (Facebook, 2016: 37). The upshot
is that when information is a commodity and all else takes a back seat, inequality is the norm.
Following Marx’s injunction that the critique of capitalism starts with the commodity, Schiller and
Smythe began their respective analyses with the media economy's central commodities: audiences
and information.
Communications generalize capitalism and the commodity form to more areas of people’s lives,
and to more markets and areas of the world. The process incorporated: Europe (the Marshall Plan);
the ‘third world’ circa the 1950s through to the 1970s (modernization theory); Russia and the
‘eastern bloc’ countries’ after the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989 (third wave democracy); and the
remaking of China into an authoritarian capitalist society reintegrated into the world economy since
the 1990s (post Washington Consensus world). As Marx said, capitalism is a dynamic and forever
expanding system, always seeking out new domains of accumulation, whether in the mind or in new
geographical markets.
The fusion of telecommunications, computing and information technologies had advanced
considerably by the time that Smythe and Schiller were writing. Fueled by the Cold War, close to
three-quarters of all R&D funding in computing and electronics in the US up to the mid-1970s
came from the US government and military. Of course, the latter stages of this period are when
Arpanet, the military-led precursor of the internet, was developed. Although neither Schiller nor
Smythe had anything to say about the internet, they illuminated the geopolitical and economic
forces that were driving the ‘information revolution’ and the global expansion of capitalism.
Consequently, they regarded the ideals of a free press within the capitalist democracies of North
America and Europe, and the free flow of information on the world stage as an ideological ruse
used to divert attention from the media's power and the opening of world markets to U.S. and
European firms. Whereas past forms of imperialism had rested on territorial occupation and military
might, the US Empire of capital rested on cultural imperialism, backstopped by US military might.
Britain’s imperial power in the 19th and first half of the 20th century had stemmed from its control
of a vast global system of submarine cable and wireless communications, Schiller and others
argued. In the post-World War II order, with the US’s unrivaled economic and military ascendency,
the ‘free flow of information’ became the cornerstone of communication policy. US businesses,
government, and media could thereby coordinate their efforts to recreate the world in their image
Winseck 92
[14]. Communications technologies are hardly technologies of freedom; they are weapons of
politics and guarantors of world hegemony (Headrick, 1991). We must regard communications
technology in the context of the military doctrine of Communication, Command, Control and
Information (C3I) (which recent writers refer to as the Military-Information-Media and
Entertainment Complex) (Mirlees, 2015).
Smythe and Schiller’s efforts helped to forge links between leftist researchers from North
America and Europe with politicians, scholars, activists, and media workers in the Global South.
This formed part of a late 1970s movement to redress imbalances in the distribution of
communication resources between rich and poor countries. Efforts to establish a New World
Information and Communication Order (NWICO) under the auspices of the United Nations
Education, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) made real headway, but lost force in
the 1980s. The US, UK, and Singapore withdrew from UNESCO in opposition to NWICO and the
‘politicization of global communication’, and threaten to do the same to the ITU, the world’s oldest
multilateral governance organization.
Smythe and Schiller’s work has inspired generations of scholars around the world ever since,
although some criticized the pair's core assumptions. Graham Murdock and Peter Golding (1974;
1995), for example, argued that the industrialization of the media during the 20th century required a
Marxist economic analysis of the media, linked to an understanding of how such processes left
traceable consequences on, and set broad limits for, cultural expression. According to them,
capitalist media development starts with the industrialization and commercialization of cultural
forms that had once existed outside the market. They were previously supported by
paying/participating publics, the patronage of wealthy backers, or subsidies (from the government
and other sources). However, unlike Smythe or Schiller, Murdock and Golding were quick to note
that the American experience was not the same as the British, Canadian or European experience,
where public service media and the role of ‘the state’ was stronger. Newly commercialized media
also confront an inevitable problem: the amount of time, money and attention people spend on
media goods stays relatively fixed. Nicholas Garnham (1990) called this ‘the law of relatively
constant expenditure’, and insofar that it is used to study household spending on media content and
cultural services (e.g. concerts, plays, sports, etc.) the claim still holds up well (although not for
expenditure on ‘connectivity’ and ‘devices’).
According to Murdock and Golding (1974), constrained by such realities, but spurred on by the
never-ending imperative to grow or die, media companies adopt strategies of consolidation
(horizontal and vertical integration), diversification into new areas (notably the leisure market), and
internationalization. In later iterations of their work, they add that governments play a large role in
expanding markets by privatizing publicly owned telecommunications enterprises and broadcasters,
commercializing public service media and liberalizing market access to these industries to domestic
and foreign investors (Golding and Murdock, 2005).
Murdock and Golding’s view is that the logic of capitalism as an economic system drives and
constrains developments in media (rather than the personal and political interests of media barons).
While they point to the constraining influence of economics on cultural expression, they reject the
instrumentalist idea of direct editorial control over content from media owners and executives.
Along with other political economists, notably Nicholas Garnham (1990; 2011) and Bernard Miege
(1989; 2011), they explicitly rejected the dominant ideology thesis. Murdock (1982) has observed
these trends closely, and his 1982 piece on the subject cautions that such trends can be overdrawn.
Whether ownership is by moguls or the great money managers at investment banks, the common
Winseck 93
thread is that both control resources while making the big, long-term policy and resource allocation
decisions that shape everything else that follows thereafter (Murdock, 1982; Murdock, 2016). This
is structural power, the setting of broad constraints on what kinds of media content gets produced
and how the whole enterprise generally operates in the long-term.
For more than three decades, the US scholar Janet Wasko has also made significant
contributions to the Marxist PEC tradition through her work on the American and international film
industries. She has paid close attention to the links between the movie industry and banks from the
1920s. The latter have consistently helped to finance films and, via interlocking directorships and
control over the purse strings, maintained a large say in film company decision-making processes.
Wasko has also tracked consolidation in the industry, horizontally and vertically, while
documenting countervailing trends such as the breakup of vertical integration after the Supreme
Court’s 1948 Paramount Decision. This led the big Hollywood studios to sell-off of the theaters
they had owned up until that point. Power within the film industry thereafter, as Wasko and others
observe, shifted from film production and vertical integration over the entire supply chain to a focus
on the control of distribution, finance, and copyright (Aksoy & Robins, 1992; Christopherson,
2011; Wasko, 2004). She has also emphasized the strategies used by the industry to manage risks in
the face of technological change, the rise of new centres of production, and the vagaries of
audiences’ tastes. Such strategies include distributing fewer big-budget blockbusters but with ever
larger promotional budgets, subcontracting to (semi-) independent filmmakers but often acquiring
such firms once they reach a certain scale (as Disney, for example, has done with Pixar and Lucas
Films) and relying on sequels with brand familiarity, cross-marketing, synergy and merchandising.
Also important is the careful maintenance of the ‘windows strategy’ that separates media markets
by geography, time and medium so as to protect the value of each market. The windows model
remains the lynchpin of the audiovisual media industries to date, even if it is being challenged by
over-the-top internet-based audiovisual media and piracy (Evans and MacDonald, 2014).
American scholar, Robert McChesney, has been one of the most influential critical PEC scholars,
and has done much to popularize the approach across academic disciplines and to a broader
audience. In his early historical work on radio, and his more recent analyses, McChesney has
adopted a relatively straightforward, ‘three-tier’ model of national and global media systems. The
first tier consists of six to ten major media conglomerates that dominate film, television, music,
radio, cable and satellite, publishing, and the internet. Another fifteen to twenty firms in the U.S.,
and about three dozen worldwide make up the second tier. The third tier consists of thousands of
voices that “fill the nooks and crannies of the media system” (McChesney, 2004: 183). Taken as a
whole, the tiered system is also defined by strategic alliances designed to blunt the sharp edge of
competition. Whatever independent voices there are tend to be marginal, precariously situated and
far less effective than they might otherwise be in a ‘real democracy’.
McChesney’s most recent book, Digital Disconnect (2014), provides an up-to-date account of
capitalism in the age of the internet. Here McChesney argues that despite all the hyperbole about
how the internet would bring about a new economy, a new golden age for democracy, and break up
the high levels of concentration in ‘traditional media’, none of this has come to pass. Indeed, as he
argues, far from toppling the old three-tiered model of the traditional media in which power is
concentrated at the top of the pyramid, internet giants like Apple, Facebook, and Google have come
to dominate core elements of the internet in a similar fashion (through search, browsers, social
media, operating systems, and devices). Well-established telecoms and media giants like Verizon,
AT&T, Deutsche Telecom, Bell Canada, Time Warner, News Corp and Disney still dominate some
Winseck 94
parts of the ‘old’ media alongside the internet. Drawing on extensive and authoritative data from the
US Census Bureau and industry sources, McChesney also shows that these trends are not confined
to the communication and media industries. The number of industries where concentration levels
are high has grown, and concentration levels within industries have risen over time – the exact
opposite of what the internet optimists predicted.
The central paradox of our times, according to McChesney (and others), is that while the
internet and smartphones have given us more capacity than ever to access, share and create different
kinds of media, those same capabilities are threatening the economic development of markets for
books, news, music, movies and education (while also facilitating new access to them in the sense
that they are essential to the viable functioning of democracy). The collapse of advertising as a
viable business model as well as challenges to other kinds of media and cultural production is
threatening professional journalism and some other forms of media production like never before. As
the advertising-based model collapses the void that has opened up is being filled by sponsored
content and a deluge of public relations material. Meanwhile, faltering newspapers are acquired by
rich patrons (e.g. Jeff Bezos of Amazon’s ‘rescue’ of the Washington Post).
Even from the perspective of liberal political theory, information and media products are public
goods. This is due to their historical and philosophical association with human development and
democracy. Additionally, journalism bears other core traits of a public good from the perspective of
mainstream economics: the cost of reproducing news and information is typically next to nothing,
or little more than the ‘container’ in which they are stored (in the internet age, this cost is
effectively zero). News is also not ‘used up’ when consumed, there is more than enough ‘left’ to go
around. The theory and practice of both copyright law and democracy reflect these realities, as does
information policy in general - at least to some extent. McChesney’s project in the US context
resonates with American political traditions that can be mobilized to justify political and policy
measures to support, for instance, a more democratic, non-commercial internet and media sector.
His ideas also comport with people’s experience. Having been socialized for over a century into a
reality where journalism and universal access to broadcasting have been heavily subsidized by
advertising and government funding, is it any wonder that people are unwilling today to pay for
content that is streamed or downloaded over the internet? (Evans and McDonald, 2014: 168-169;
Laboto and Thomas, 2015). While such considerations are often overruled by the fact that
information is traded in a market, with the public good aspects swept under the rug, these realities
are never fully erasable. Hence, the politics of information/knowledge that such realities give rise to
are never-ending (Babe, 1995; Benkler, 2006; Melody, 1987).
the pervasive role of uncertainty across all levels of the media (Bustamante, 2004: 805; Garnham,
2011).
Writing a quarter-of-a-century ago, Bernard Miege (1989) crystallized the gist of these
criticisms in a slim, but extremely valuable volume, The Capitalization of Cultural Production [15].
Of these, four stand out:
First, referring to the industry or ‘system’ “in the singular misleads one into
thinking that we are faced with a unified field, where the various elements
function within a single process . . . The cultural industries are complex, and
an analysis must bring out the reasons for this diversity”;
Second, the line between culture and commerce drawn by Marxist PEC
ignores the fact that culture has developed within industrial capitalism for the
past one hundred and fifty years.
Third, the “distrust of technology and artistic innovation” implied by such
views is excessive and unnecessary.
Finally, “new communication technologies . . . contribute to tightening the
hold of capitalist production over culture as well as communication, however,
this does not mean that the capitalist industrialization of culture has been fully
realized . . .” (10-11).
While critical PEC scholars have insisted on taking a holistic approach to the social totality of
capitalism (Fuchs, 2011; Golding and Murdock, 2005; Mosco, 2009), such a focus risks obscuring
too much detail. Zygmunt Bauman (2000) and Luc Botanski (2011) argue that taking the ‘social
totality’ as a starting point obscures the more pressing fact that modern capitalist societies, social
institutions and individual life biographies are precarious, fragmented and riven with cross-cutting
complexities and instabilities. For all the talk of commodification, neoliberalism, deregulation,
privatization, globalization, and so on, none of these processes comes in a one-size-fits-all form.
Instead, they need to be seen as differentiated across time, space and media. Moreover, they do not
unfold uni-directionally, and are subject to reversal and failure -- the arrow of change points in
more than one direction (Arrighi, 2009; Brenner, Peck & Theodor, 2010).
Just as there are ‘varieties of capitalism’, so too there are ‘varieties of PEC’. Besides critical or
Marxist PEC, the institutionalist and Cultural Industries schools are the most important. Many
scholars identify with one or the other. Take, for example, the institutionalist scholar William
Melody. Like Dallas Smythe before him, Melody was also the chief economist at the FCC from
1966 to 1971. He was also Smythe’s colleague at Simon Fraser University in Canada in the 1970s
and early-1980s. For a half-century, Melody has mentored several generations of students at Simon
Fraser University, the Annenberg Program at the University of Pennsylvania and Oxford
University. While at the latter institution, he was appointed Director of the Program on Information
and Communication Technologies at the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC) which
created programs at six universities in the UK. He was also involved in the Centre for International
Research on Communication and Information Technologies in Australia, Delft University in the
Netherlands as well as Aalborg University in Denmark. Melody’s research, teaching and policy
interventions have significantly advanced institutionalist approaches to the PEC. Many of his
students have become leading scholars and active participants in the ongoing battles to shape the
institutional ecology of the telecoms, internet, media and information landscape over the last
quarter-of-a-century. Such people include Robin Mansell, Anders Henten, Amy Mahan, and Rohan
Samarajiva, to name a few (Mansell, Samarajiva and Mahan, 2002; Lemstra & Melody, 2014).
Winseck 96
Melody’s work also links to that of Robert Babe and Harold Trebing, and looks backward in time to
leading figures in the early institutionalist versions of political economy set out previously:
Thorstein Veblen, John R. Commons, Frank Knight, Walter Adams, Richard Ely and Harold Innis.
In the canonical text outlining the PEC approach, however, Mosco (2009) mentions Melody’s
work only twice, and only in passing insofar as it intersects with Smythe’s career (77, 84). Yet, such
omissions are symptomatic of what passes for PEC in general in our field – an impoverished view
of its past and contemporary contributions. Consequently, many scholars no longer identify with the
PEC tradition, largely because they reject the prevalent idea in the field that it is merely thinly
veiled code for a Marxist view of the world, and bristle under pressure to conform to that fiction.
We can see the consistent outlines of Melody’s approach in The Dynamics of Broadband
Markets in Europe. In this book, he and co-editor Wolter Lemstra (2014) insist that while the
development of broadband information infrastructures is now common throughout the world, the
precise ways in which they unfold is contingent upon how technology and markets intersect with
regulation, policy and existing institutional arrangements in each country. We need an inductive
approach, historical understanding, and case studies to reveal how the same technology develops
and is used by people in different places. Does this mean, however, that “we should conclude that
every broadband market is unique and very little can be learned and shared across” countries and in
terms of “common objectives”, Lemstra and Melody ask (2-5)? Of course not. The trick is to meld
both common features and the distinctive aspects of time and place to generate insights and realistic
policy proposals. This is a reformist rather than a radical approach, in keeping with much of the
institutionalist tradition.
A current American version of the institutionalist approach can be seen in Richard John’s work
on postal, telegraph, telephone, press and news history (John, 2010; John & Silberstein-Loeb,
2016). John, a business historian at Columbia University, has emerged as an influential member of
the ‘information nation’ school of historiography in the US (Chandler & Cortada, 2003). This
school argues that understanding the institutional arrangements that have been adopted to manage
information, communication and news since the 18th Century is essential to understanding the
development of US-style capitalism and republican democracy. The approach is also indebted to
Beninger’s (1989) view that systematic efforts by governments and industry from the 19th century
onward to better gather, store and manage information were responses to early perceptions of a
‘crisis of control’. This concept had been thrown up by the sheer scale of the US, and it profoundly
shaped its national development. In line with long standing divides in the social sciences, the
approach is more Weberian than Marxian.
Yochai Benkler’s account of the ongoing transformation of the ‘industrial media era’ of the past
one hundred and fifty years to the network information economy and network public sphere of the
21st Century is also relevant here. He is another scholar who explicitly self-identifies as a political
economist, but of the liberal rather than Marxist kind. Indeed, there is a great deal of this type of
research in law schools at Columbia (Tim Wu), Stanford (Lawrence Lessig) and Harvard (Yochai
Benkler, Susan Crawford, Jonathan Zittrain) [16]. Their work, however, hardly ever figures in the
accounts of critical PEC scholars except as a foil (a supposed reservoir of internet exceptionalism
and technotopian views) against which Critical PEC scholars aim to set things right. Their ideas are
not so easily reduced to such caricatures, however, and have gained a warmer reception by media
industries scholars who study the internet as the infrastructure of the emerging system of ‘connected
viewing’ for TV, film and other audiovisual media (Holt and Sanson, 2014). They are also in line
with some critical political economists like Peter Thompson (2011) and Scott Fitzgerald (2011),
Winseck 97
who highlight the institutional factors that distinguish media enterprises and industries (and their
associated operating logics, policy regimes, and place within the broader political economy).
Bounding our objects of analysis: What’s in, what’s out and why
In order to outline a research agenda that is do-able, I refer here to about a dozen or so of the largest
telecoms, internet and media industries, based on revenue: i.e. mobile wireless services, wireline
telecoms services, internet access, cable, satellite and IPTV distribution infrastructures, broadcast
TV, pay TV, film, music, video games, radio, internet advertising, newspapers, books and
magazines. I call the sum total of these elements the network media ecology.
In this context, the media infrastructure industries have become the centre of gravity around
which the rest of the media turns. Indeed, revenues for such industries are nearly three times those
of the media content sectors (Noam, 2016: 1054; Winseck, 2015: 6) [17]. This is the ‘economic
base’ of the evermore internet- and mobile wireless-centric media universe, where bandwidth is
king, not content.
The economic base of the network media is now also based mainly on subscriber fees and the
pay-per model (Mosco, 1989). Indeed, subscription fees and direct commodification outstrip
advertising by roughly a 3:1 ratio. As a rule, the platform-based and pay-per media are growing
fast. They also tend to be highly concentrated in certain areas (e.g. internet access, mobile wireless,
pay TV, video games). In contrast, content-based media have stagnated or grown slowly in recent
years (e.g. radio, movies). They are generally less concentrated than ‘platform media’, mostly
because they are less capital intensive. In addition, the more a medium relies on advertising and
content, the more likely it is to be in trouble (e.g. newspapers, magazines, broadcast TV in some
countries) (Miege, 2011; Noam, 2016: 1264-1266; Preston and Rogers, 2012). Moreover, pay-per
media have generally weathered economic crises and the transition to the internet- and mobile-
wireless centric media ecology better than advertising-supported media. Of course, internet
advertising is a major exception to that general rule. We must also bear in mind that some media
that have recently been at death’s door (e.g. music, books and postal services) appear to be
recovering. The directions of the changes taking place are, in short, cross-cutting, and not all of a
single kind.
For example, as journalism undergoes a wrenching crisis and firms scale back, spin-off assets
and, in some cases, go bankrupt, the newspaper industry has become less concentrated as some new
players enter the scene to pick up the wreckage. In addition, in the late-1990s, the trend toward
vertical integration involving telecoms-internet operators, on one side, and media and entertainment
companies, on the other, has turned. Many telecom-internet-media conglomerates formed at the
time have been dismantled (e.g. AOL Time Warner, AT&T, Vivendi, Adelphia, CBS-Viacom,
News Corp, etc), while levels of vertical integration between carriers and content is now much
lower than it was at the turn-of-the-21st Century in many countries. To be sure, many have
highlighted the crisis of journalism (e.g. Almiron, 2010; McChesney, 2014), and some have
encapsulated the break-up of vertically-integrated telecoms-internet and media conglomerates in
terms of ‘deconvergence’ (Jin, 2011), but the idea of “a settled structure” for the telecoms, media
and Internet sectors still “remains a mirage” (Curwen, 2008: 3).
Moreover, not all media firms are conglomerates. In the music industries, for example,
‘diversified’ and/or ‘media’ conglomerates once ruled but no longer do. There are only three of the
big recorded-music giants left: Sony, Warner and Universal. Only Sony is part of an ICT-based
conglomerate, while Warner and Universal were spun off from their conglomerate overlords long
ago. The Big Three’s share of ‘total music industry’ revenue (i.e. recorded music, publishing,
concerts, digital/online) has also contracted greatly, largely because the ‘recorded music’ segment
Winseck 99
of the industry that they have historically dominated has shrunk drastically. It should be
acknowledged here that music publishing has held steady while digital and live music have soared.
This means that the industry as a whole has stayed about the same size on the basis of revenue, even
ticking upwards in the last few years (Fitzgerald, 2012; IFPI, 2015; Winseck, 2015).
Take another example: Canada, where four vertically integrated telecoms and TV giants account
for nearly 60% of all revenue in the ‘network media economy’. In fact, in Canada, all the major pay
and conventional television services, except those of the CBC, the public broadcaster, are owned by
the telephone-ISP companies. Levels of vertical integration in Canada have also grown greatly over
time and within a much bigger media economy. Such trends are also unusual by international
comparative standards (Winseck, 2015: 16). The only comparable example in the US, for example,
is Comcast. Its share of a roughly drawn ‘total network media economy’, however, is 11% - a third
of that of the largest player in Canada, Bell Canada Enterprises. And unlike Canada, Comcast is not
a mobile phone company. In addition, none of the major TV services in the US, other than NBC
Universal (owned by Comcast), are owned by the telecoms operators. Vertical integration in the US
is lower now by far than at the turn-of-the-21st century (Skorup and Thierer, 2012; Noam, 2016).
AT&T’s acquisition of DirecTV in 2015 is important, but it is a distributor with no appreciable
stakes in TV content other than some small stakes in a few regional sports services. In the US, the
vertical integration that does exist takes on a different form whereby the major film companies have
big stakes in the television industry. Such differences fundamentally shape the nature of different
media economies, and must be accounted for rather than glossed over by abstract models of
capitalism and the culture industries.
Changes in the economic base and implications for critique: From the
audience commodity to what people really want
Over the past decade, many scholars have focused political-economic critique on the unpaid digital
labor that ‘prosumers’ provide as they Tweet, post to Facebook, upload videos to YouTube, and
otherwise produce content that feeds internet companies’ bottom line (e.g. Fuchs, 2012; McGuigan
and Manzerolle, 2015; also see the special issue of the Information Society, 2015). In other words,
today's prosumers are to the internet what living room audiences were to commercial mass media: a
commodity. Seen from this view, the terms of service agreements of Facebook, Google or Twitter,
or Yandex and Baidu in Russia and China, are embodiments of alienation, given that all users must
click on, and accept, them before using the ‘platform’. There is no choice: click yes or leave. The
intimate spaces of people’s lives have been colonized as a result by the systematic collection,
retention and use of their data for commercial ends, data which has also ended up, unwittingly or
otherwise, serving the national security interests of Western intelligence services and governments
around the world.
Shoshana Zuboff (2015) sees these activities as being a part of “surveillance capitalism”, based
on a process of primitive accumulation, where things held in common or as an integral part of one’s
being are taken without permission and made into commodities and private property. In a recent
example of this Google ingested 11,000 books from an online repository available to all in order to
use the large corpus of literature to train its artificial intelligence systems. None of the authors
whose books were used were consulted. However, once some did discover that their work was
being used in this way without their knowledge or consent they were predictably not pleased, yet
felt helpless in terms of meaningful recourse (Lea, 2016). Samuelson (2011) argues that a similar
Winseck 100
logic underpins Google’s ‘Book Project’, in which the company basically does an end-run around
existing copyright law in the hope that it will be able to subsequently remake the law in light of the
new facts it has created on the ground. This is hubris on a monumental scale operating at the edges
of the ‘rule-of-law’ (itself a basic precondition of a democratic society).
The idea of audience labour and the audience commodity offers a critical perspective on the
internet and the economic model supporting it. Focusing on advertising-supported, ‘free media’,
however, when such media are already vastly outstripped by media that people pay for directly,
hitches the ‘audience commodity’ thesis to a receding part of the media economy. Moreover, there
is no relationship between the time people spend on Facebook and profit levels for example; the
company accrues around $31 per user per year in North America. This is less than half the ARPU
(average revenue per user) for mobile wireless services that Verizon, AT&T, BT, or Bell, for
example, obtain in a single month (Facebook, 2016: 37). The thesis also reduces human experience
to a one-dimensional view of labour. Yet, rather than toiling away for nothing, people continue to
create, share and consume a lot of information, culture and media goods for many reasons that have
little to do with market forces and much to do with pleasure, human interaction, status, intimacy,
goofing off and other forms of expression (Benkler, 2006; Garnham, 1990; Miege, 1989; Lobato
and Thomas, 2015).
Instead of critique resting on the labour theory of value (or on how the structure of the media
influences content), it may be more useful to set out new anchors for ‘immanent critique’ based on
how people think about and use the communications media at their disposal. In this view, the stress
is on what technologies and business arrangements enable and what they constrain through, for
example, the ‘pricing mechanism’, as Veblen might say. Such matters include subscriber fees, data
caps on mobile phone and internet access, the zero-rating of some services by ISPs and mobile
wireless carriers but not others, and steep ‘overage charges’ when those caps are exceeded (as if
people are using ‘too much’ internet). Immanent critique would also take what people say, and how
they use media, in relation to privacy, control over their personal communications and surveillance
to heart - pace Mills and Habermas - by institutionalizing markets, technology designs and
regulatory frameworks that respond to people’s expressed interests (see Nissenbaum, 2010). As
Turow, Hennessy and Draper (2015) have shown, the vast majority of people do care about the loss
of control over their personal data and communications, but are resigned to the fact that they can do
little about it. In other words, they are alienated from their own personal communications and data,
and powerless to do much about it -- except leave, which is no choice at all.
Political economists could also look at the design of media in terms of how they enable some
uses while constraining others. For example, digital locks, which are backed by the force of the
state through copyright are used by the US to make countries adopt new copyright laws that are
longer, broader and stronger than ever (Haggart, 2014). In this view, immanent critique takes the
distance between what people do with media versus the technological, economic, legal and other
constraints that limit their activities as its basis. Standards of critique could be derived from studies
of the social uses, and critical theories, of technology found in, say, Mansell and Silverstone’s
Communication by Design (1996), Andrew Feenberg’s Critical Theory of Technology (2010) and
Gerard Goggin’s Global Mobile Media (2011). Critical social theories of communication, trust and
labour, as articulated by, for example, Jurgen Habermas, Axel Honneth, and Karl Marx, also offer a
guide, although one should not rely on any one of these sources exclusively.
Winseck 101
so, it stood down one of the biggest internet giants in the world, Facebook, as well as the company’s
hired guns drawn from the ranks of US think tanks and economic consultancies.
In sum, regulators are not just paper tigers. In many countries, they are a significant counter to
market power and they act in the name of values that are worth supporting. Their actions also
suggest that the ‘free market’ orthodoxy of neoliberal globalization no longer reigns supreme. PEC
scholars must grapple with the messy details of technical and regulatory matters like bandwidth,
data caps, common carriage, spectrum and the arcane rules and procedures of regulatory processes.
Only then will they influence the results of ongoing battles over the institutional ecology of the
emergent internet-mobile-wireless-centric communications across the media landscape.
revealing the extent of US hegemony over the internet to illustrate that the internet is a jointly-
constructed set of nearly 50,000 interoperating networks (e.g. autonomous system numbers, or
ASN), all of which are under varying degrees of government oversight. The five eyes agreements
between the Anglo powers (the US, UK, Australia, Canada and New Zealand) at the heart of the
Snowden revelations are analogous to similar operations by the intelligence services in Germany,
Switzerland, Sweden, France, Russia, China, and, probably every country that has the resources to
do such work.
The assemblage of submarine fibre optic cables, cable landing points, IXPs, ASN and data
centres that comprise the hardware of the internet is, in fact, becoming more polycentric in terms of
the countries where it is based and the type of players that own and control it. Tata, for example, is
an Indian mega-industrial conglomerate that is also the owner-operator of one of the biggest
submarine fibre optic networks in the world (and one of the largest mobile wireless networks in
India). Indeed, so much has the centre of gravity shifted towards Europe, Asia and the rest of the
world, that allegations of US-internet imperialism seem far-fetched (Powers and Jablonski, 2015;
Fuchs, 2010; Jin, 2014). The US government and the giant American internet companies continue
to dominate some core elements of the internet (e.g. operating systems, internet content, social
networks and search engines). However, the influence of American capital and the US state is
receding when it comes to the hard infrastructure of the internet. In addition, claims of US internet
imperialism obscure the complex web of global alliances and transactions that underpin the global
internet infrastructure in the ‘real world’.
Author Bio
Dwayne is Professor at the School of Journalism and Communication, Carleton University, Ottawa
and Director of the Canadian Media Concentration Research (CMCR) Project. His research has
been cited widely in the literature, the press and regulators. He was a regular columnist at the Globe
and Mail, and maintains the Mediamorphis <dwmw.wordpress.org> and CMCR Project
<cmcrp.org> blogs. His co-authored book with Robert Pike Communication and Empire won the
Canadian Communication Association’s book-of-the-year prize in 2008. He is also co-editor, with
Winseck 105
Dal Yong Jin, of Political Economies of the Media (2011) and several other edited and sole-
authored books.
Endnotes
[1] ‘Media infrastructure’ industries refers to mobile wireless, broadband internet
access, basic telephone service and cable, satellite and Internet-Protocol
Television (IPTV) services. They provide people (subscribers) with access to
services over the internet (networks) and are generally paid for mostly through
subscriptions versus advertising.
[2] Cunningham, Flew and Swift do not cite any literature from the PEC tradition
to support their charges on this point (see chapter 2).
[3] For instance, Edison originally thought of records as a way to preserve speech
for future playback, not music, and telephone companies in Hungary, Italy,
Canada, the UK, US, etc. all experimented for years with ‘broadcasting
services’, including live theatre, church sermons, newspaper readings, etc. The
ultimate use of both media were considerably different than these early visions
imagined (Gitelman, 2006, Balbi, 2010).
[4] One of the founding figures in the institutional PEC tradition, Thorstein
Veblen (1921), might explain this as a process by which ‘industry’ - basically,
the application of the sum-total of a society’s ‘practical’ knowledge, creativity
and efficiency to technology, automation and machines - is subjugated to
‘business’, This is the organizational form of capital; the firm keeps prices and
profits high, to exercise control over an uncertain environment, and over
society’s productive capacity, creativity and efficiency (i.e. technology) for as
long as it can (Nitzan and Bichler, 2009). Veblen’s view of technology as a
society’s stock of knowledge accords with Marx’s views regarding technology
as the embodiment of the ‘general intellect’ in his ‘fragment on machines’.
Such a view differs from those held in some Marxist circles whereby
technology is reduced to being the embodiment and tool of capitalist interests.
Thanks to Illijan Shehu, a PhD student in the Institute of Political Economy at
Carleton University, for helping me clarify Veblen’s ideas on this point, and
for pointing to Nitzan and Bichler’s book on Veblen.
[5] Ross received his Ph.D. in political economy at John Hopkins University in the
US in 1891. In the three years before, he had been a visiting scholar in
Germany, the UK and France. In France, he was greatly influenced by
Gabriele Tarde, a highly respected early theorist of public opinion. In his book
Social Psychology (1908), Ross paid a “heartfelt homage to the genius of
Gabriel Tarde” (viii). In Social Control (1901), he refers to Albion Small,
another key figure in the development of communication studies, in a similar
way (vii).
[6] The old legal construct was known as the ‘Blackstonian’ model of property,
named after the English legal scholar Lord Blackstone who formalized it.
[7] A similar process took place in the UK two decades earlier, largely around
cases involving specialized financial market and sporting information services
(Winseck, 1999: 150).
Winseck 106
[8] Today, we see much the same thing on the balance sheets of mobile wireless
operators.
[9] The ‘iron triangle of information power’ was put on a permanent wartime
footing after WWII when the National Security Agency was formalized in
1952 (it was publicly unknown until decades later). Cooperative arrangements
were already in place five years earlier between its predecessor and the rest of
the US ‘Five Eyes’ partners (Australia, Canada, New Zealand and the UK) for
international ‘signals intelligence’ work. Putting ‘the iron triangle of
information power’ on a permanent wartime footing after WWII laid the basis
for mass internet surveillance in our own time.
[10] Note that by this point that we have four different moments when the critique
of ideology has been eroded or abandoned: (1) Ross and Bucher, on the
grounds that the personal and political interests of the media mogul were being
replaced by capitalist enterprise and the pursuit of profit; (2) Adorno by
turning from the critique of ideology to the critique of instrumental reason; (3)
Mills, because people have retained independence of mind and the ability to
speak and form public opinion, despite the “system” being deaf and dumb to
their views; and (4) Habermas, who we might charitably say combines
elements from all of above.
[11] By which the DOJ and FCC meant the effect that the transaction would have
on both ITT and ABC’s influence as separate, competing enterprises on (1)
advertising markets; (2) the TV market where ITT had the resources to enter as
a new TV network, and thus to increase diversity; and (3) the then
fundamentally new information infrastructures being imagined as the
foundation of “wired cities”. These infrastructures included CATV and
satellite systems. The DOJ and FCC’s standpoint was consistent with the long-
standing policy principle regarding market segmentation/media divergence
outlined earlier (Levin, 1969: 466).
[12] Cannon (2003) sees the Computer Inquires as fundamental to the development
of the internet by controlling the telephone companies’ role in the nascent
computing and information services field.
[13] Yochai Benkler (1998) later referred to Innis’ work in this regard as “a
fountainhead of . . . the political economy of communication” (184, fn 3).
[14] The historical basis and theory of geopolitics upon which claims about cultural
imperialism and the American Empire are based are problematic for reasons
hinted at earlier. The free flow of information did not emerge after WWII, but
was a part of US international communications policy since the late-19th
Century, and in a formal but failed effort immediately after WWI. Seeing the
US state and businesses as joined at the hip ignores the fact that there were
cleavages within the latter, and between some communication companies and
the US Government. This meant that Wilson’s bid to promote the free flow
doctrine as the basis for restoring liberal internationalism/imperialism
immediately after WWI was dead on arrival. The tight coupling between the
nation-state and business interests neglects the more cosmopolitan,
multinational and collaborative nature of global capitalist imperialism and
modernity (Conant, 1898; Rogers, 1920; Winseck and Pike, 2007).
Winseck 107
[15] Miege’s criticisms were related directly to Theodor Adorno’s Culture Industry
thesis, but it is clear that the criticisms can be applied to neoclassical
economics and the Monopoly Capitalism School as well.
References
Abbate J (1999) Inventing the internet. Cambridge, MA: MIT.
Abercrombie N, Hill S and Turner B (1980) The dominant ideology thesis. New York: Harper Collins.
Adams W (1954) The ‘rule of reason’: Workable competition or workable monopoly? Yale Law Journal
63(3): 348-370.
Arrighi G (2009) Adam Smith in Beijing. London: Verso.
Aksoy A and Robins K (1992) Hollywood for the twenty-first century. Cambridge Journal of Economics
16(1): 1-22.
Almiron N (2010) Journalism in crisis: Corporate media and financialization. Cresskill, NJ: Hampton.
Andrejevic M (2009) Critical media studies 2.0. Interactions: Studies in communication and culture 1(1), 35-
51.
Babe R (1995) Communication and the transformation of economics. Boulder, CO: Westview.
Bakker G (2008) Entertainment industrialised: The emergence of the international film industry, 1890-1940.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University.
Balbi G (2010) Radio before radio: Araldo Telefonico and the invention of Italian broadcasting. Technology
and Culture 51(4): 786-808.
Baran P and Sweezy P (1966) Monopoly capital. New York: Monthly Review.
Barnouw E (1975) Tube of plenty. New York: Oxford University.
Bauman Z (2000) Liquid modernity. London: Blackwell-Wiley.
Beck U (2005) Power in the global age. London: Polity.
Beniger J (1989) The control revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Benkler Y (2006) The wealth of networks. New Haven, CN: Yale University.
Benkler Y (1998) Communications infrastructure regulation and the distribution of control over content.
Telecommunications Policy 22(3): 183-196.
Winseck 108
Benkler Y, Faris R, Gasser U, Miyakawa L and Schultze S (2010) Next generation connectivity. Cambridge,
MA: Berkman Center for Internet & Society. Available at:
http://cyber.law.harvard.edu/publications/2010/Next_Generation_Connectivity (accessed 12
December 2016).
Blondheim M (2004) Rehearsal for media regulation, Federal Communications Law Journal 56: 299-328.
Boltanski L (2011) On critique. London: Polity.
Boyle J (1996) Shamans, software and spleens. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Britain Pacific Cable Committee (1899) Report, minutes and proceedings, etc. London: Darlington and Sons.
Brenner N, Peck J and Theodor N (2010) After neoliberalism? Globalizations 7(3), 327-345.
Broadband Commission (2015) The state of broadband 2015. Geneva, Switzerland: ITU and UNESCO.
Available at: http://www.broadbandcommission.org/documents/reports/bb-annualreport2015.pdf
(accessed 12 December 2016).
Bustamante E (2004) Cultural industries in the digital age. Media, culture & society 26(6): 803-820.
Calhoun C (1992) The infrastructure of modernity. In: Haferkamp H and Smelser NJ (Eds) Social change
and modernity. Berkeley, CA: University of California, pp. 88-114.
Canadian Radio-television and Telecommunications Commission (2015a) Regulatory framework for mobile
wireless wholesale services. Available at: http://www.crtc.gc.ca/eng/archive/2015/2015-177.pdf
(accessed 12 December 2016).
Canadian Radio-television and Telecommunications Commission (2015b) Review of wholesale wireline
services and associated policies. Available at: http://www.crtc.gc.ca/eng/archive/2015/2015-326.pdf
(accessed 12 December 2016).
Cannon R (2003) The legacy of the Federal Communications Commission’s computer inquiries. Federal
Communications Law Journal 55(2): 167-205. Available at
http://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1324&context=fclj (accessed 12
December 2016).
Chandler A and Cortada J (2003) A nation transformed by information. New York: Oxford University.
Christopherson C (2011) Hard jobs in Hollywood. In: Winseck D & Jin DY (Eds) Political economies of the
media. London: Bloomsbury, pp. 123-141.
Coase R (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4: 386-405
Cooley CH (1910/1918) Political economy and social process. Journal of Political Economy 26(4): 366-374.
Conant C (1898) The economic basis of imperialism, North American Review 167: 326-46.
Conant M (1960) Antitrust in the motion picture industry. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University.
Cunningham S, Flew T and Swift A (2015) Media eEconomics. London: Palgrave.
Curwen P (2008) A settled structure for the TMT sector remains a mirage in 2006/7. Info 10(2): 3-23.
Danielian NR (1939) AT&T: The story of industrial conquest. New York: Vanguard.
European Parliament (2014) Draft report on the US NSA surveillance programme, surveillance bodies in
various member states and their impact on E.U. citizens’ fundamental rights and on transatlantic
cooperation in justice and home affairs. Brussels: Author. Available at:
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2009_2014/documents/libe/dv/moraes_1014703_/moraes_
1014703_en.pdf (accessed 12 December 2016)
Winseck 109
Evans E and McDonald P (2014) Online distribution of film and television in the UK. In: Hold J and Sanson
K (Eds) Connected viewing. New York: Routledge, pp. 158-180.
Facebook Inc. (2016) Annual report 2015. Menlo Park, CA: Author. Available at:
https://s21.q4cdn.com/399680738/files/doc_financials/annual_reports/2015-Annual-Report.pdf
(accessed 12 December 2016).
Federal Communications Commission (2016) Charter Communications, Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc., and
Advance/Newhouse Partnership MB Docket No. 15-149. Memorandum opinion and order.
Available at: https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-16-59A1.pdf (accessed 12
December 2016).
Federal Communications Commission (2015) Protecting and promoting the open internet. Washington, DC:
Author. https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-15-24A1.pdf (accessed 12 December
2016).
Federal Communications Commission (2011) Memorandum opinion and order in the matter of applications
of Comcast Corporation, General Electric Company and NBC Universal. Available at:
http://transition.fcc.gov/transaction/comcast-nbcu.html (accessed 12 December 2016).
Feenberg A (2010) Between reason and experience. Boston, MA: MIT.
Fitzgerald S (2012) Corporations and the cultural industries. Lanham, ML: Lexington.
Fuchs C (2012) Dallas Smythe today: The audience commodity, the digital labour debate, Marxist political
economy and critical theory. triple 10(2): 692-740.
Fuchs, C (2010) New imperialism. tripleC 6(1): 33-60.
Gandy O (1993) The panoptic sort. Boulder, CO: Westview.
Garnham N (2011) The political economy of communication revisited. In: Wasko J, Murdock G and Sousa
H (Eds). The handbook of political economy of communications. London: Blackwell, pp. 41-61.
Garnham N (1990) Capitalism and communication. London: Sage.
Gillespie T, Boczkowkski PJ and Foot KA (Eds) Media technologies. Cambridge, MA: MIT.
Gitelman L (2006) Always already new. Cambridge, MA: MIT.
Goggin G (2011) Global mobile media. London: Routledge.
Great Britain Pacific Cable Committee (1899) Report, minutes and proceedings, etc. London: Darlington and
Sons.
Habermas J (1987) Theory of communicative action (vol. 2). Boston: Beacon.
Haggart B (2014) Copyfight. Toronto: University of Toronto.
Hardt H (2001) Social theories of the press. Lanham, MA: Rowman and Littlefield.
Hardy J (2014) Critical political economy of communications. International Journal of Media & Cultural
Politics 10(2), 189-201.
Haven T, Lotz A and Tinic S (2009) Critical media industry studies: A research approach. Communication,
Culture & Critique 2: 234–253
Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35(4): 519-530.
Headrick D (1991) The invisible weapon. London. Oxford.
Winseck 110
Hofstadter R (1965) The paranoid style of American politics and other essays. Chicago, IL: University of
Chicago.
Horkheimer M and Adorno T (1947/2002) The dialectic of enlightenment (ed. Gunzelin Schmid Noerr).
Stanford, CA: Stanford University.
Huettig M (1944) Economic control of the motion picture industry. London: Oxford.
IDATE (2009) Digiworld yearbook 2009. Montpellier, France: IDATE.
Innis H (1951) Bias of communication. Toronto: University of Toronto.
Innis H (1950) Empire and communication. Toronto: Dundurn.
IFPI (2015) Digital music report 2015. Available at http://www.ifpi.org/downloads/Digital-Music-Report-
2015.pdf (accessed 12 December 2016).
Jakobsson P and Stiernstedt F (2010) Time, space and clouds of information. Paper presented to the
International Association of Media and Communication Research Conference, July 13-17, Istanbul,
Turkey.
Jiang M (2012) Internet companies in China. Paris: IFRI Centre for Asian Studies. Available at:
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1998976 (accessed 12 December 2016).
Jin DY (2014) Platform imperialism. New York: Routledge.
Jin DY (2011) De-convergence and deconsolidation in the global media industries. In: Winseck D and Jin
DY (Eds) Political economies of the media. London: Bloomsbury, pp. 167-182.
John R (2010) Network nation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
John R and Silberstein-Loeb J (Eds) (2015) Making news. New York: Oxford University.
Kahn A (1988) The economics of regulation. Cambridge, MA: MIT.
Kahn A (1954) A legal and economic appraisal of the “new” Sherman and Clayton Acts. Yale Law Journal
63(3): 293-347.
Katz E and Lazarsfeld P (1955) Personal influence. Boston: Free Press.
Knight F (1921) Risk, uncertainty and profit. Boston: Harper.
Koskienniemi M (2002) The gentle civilizer of nations. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University.
Lazarsfeld P and Merton R (1948) Mass communication, popular taste, and organized social action. In L
Bryson (Ed) The communication of ideas. New York: Harper, pp. 95-118.
Lea R (2016) Google swallows 11,000 novels to improve AI’s conversation. The Guardian 28 September.
Lemstra W and Melody W (Eds) The dynamics of broadband markets in Europe. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge.
Levin HJ (1969) Broadcast structure, technology, and the ABC-ITT merger decision, Law
and Contemporary Problems 34(Summer): 452-484.
Lindblom C (1975) Politics and markets. New York: Basic Books.
Lippmann W (1920) Liberty and the news. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Howe.
Lobato R and Thomas J (2015) The informal media economy. London: Polity.
Mansell R (1993) The new telecommunications. London: Sage.
Mansell R and Silverstone R (Eds) (1996) Communication by design. London: Oxford University.
Winseck 111
Mansell R, Samarajiva R and Mahan A (Eds) (2002) Network knowledge for information societies.
Netherlands: Delft University.
Marx K (1867/1972) Capital: Volume one. A critical analysis of capitalist production. Reprinted in R Tucker
(Ed.) The Marx-Engels reader. London: WW Norton & Co.
Marx K and Engels F (1846/1972) The German ideology, part one Reprinted in R Tucker (Ed.) The Marx-
Engels reader. London: WW Norton & Co.
McChesney R (2014) Digital disconnect. New York: New Press.
McChesney RW (2004) The problem of the media. New York: Monthly Review.
Meehan E and Wasko J (2013) In defence of a political economy of the media. Javnost-the public 20(2): 39-
54.
McGuigan L and Manzerolle V (Eds) (2014) The audience commodity in a digital age. New York: Peter
Lang.
Melody W (1987) Information: An emerging dimension of institutional analysis. Journal of economic issues
21(3): 1313-1339.
Miege B (2011) Principle ongoing mutations of cultural and informational industries. In: Winseck D and Jin
DY (Eds) Political economies of the media. London: Bloomsbury, pp. 51-65.
Miege B (1989) The capitalization of cultural production. New York: International General.
Mills C Wright (1963) The Marxists. New York: Delta.
Mills C Wright (1956) The power elite. New York: Oxford University.
Mirlees T (2015) Hearts and mines. Vancouver, BC: UBC Press.
Mosco V (2014) Into the cloud. New York. Paradigm.
Mosco V (2009) The political economy of communication. Los Angeles: Sage.
Mosco V (1989) The pay-per society. Cresskill, NJ: Ablex.
Murdock G (2016) News Corporation. In: Birkinbine B, Gomez R and Wasko J (Eds). Global media giants.
London: Routledge, pp. 92-108.
Murdock G and Golding P (2005) Culture, communications and political economy. In: J Curran and
Gurevitch, M (Eds) Mass media and society (4th ed.). London: Hodder Arnold, pp. 63-80.
Murdock G and Golding P (1974) For a political economy of mass communications. In: Miliband R and
Saville J (Eds.) The Socialist register 1973. London: Merlin Press, pp. 205-34.
Murdock M (1982) Large corporations and communication. In: Gurevitch M, Bennett T, Curran J and
Woollacott J (Eds). Culture, media and society. London: Metheun, pp. 118-150.
Nissenbaum H (2010) Privacy in context. Stanford, CA: Standford University.
Nitzan J and Bichler S (2009) Capital as power. London: Routledge.
Noam E (Ed) (2016) Who owns the world’s media. New York: Oxford University.
Noam E (2009) Media ownership and concentration in America. New York: Oxford University.
Odlyzko A (2001) Content is not king. First Monday 6(2). Available at:
http://firstmonday.org/article/view/833/742 (accessed 12 December 2016).
Winseck 112
Ofcom (2012b) Decision to vary everything everywhere’s 1800 MHz spectrum licences to allow use of LTE
and WiMax technologies. Available at:
http://stakeholders.ofcom.org.uk/binaries/consultations/variation-900-1800mhz-lte-
wimax/statement/statement.pdf (accessed 12 December 2016).
Parthasarathi V (2005) Construing a ‘new media' market. In: Bernard B, Brouwer J, Das B, Parthasarathi V
and Poitevin G (Eds) Media and mediation. New Delhi: Sage, pp. 165-198.
Pasquale F (2015) Blackbox society. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Peters JD and Pooley JD (2012) Media and communications. In: Ritzer, G (Ed) The Wiley-Blackwell
vompanion to dociology. London: Blackwell, pp. 402-417.
Plantin J, Lagoze C, Edwards PN and Sandvig C (2016) Infrastructure studies meet platform studies in the
age of Google and Facebook. New Media and Society (preprint available at: DOI:
10.1177/1461444816661553).
Polanyi K (1944/57) The great transformation. Boston, MA: Beacon.
Powdermaker H (1950) Hollywood: The dream factory. Boston: Little, Brown & Co.
Powers S and Jablonski M (2015) The real cyberwar. Chicago, ILL: University of Illinois.
Preston P and Rogers J (2012) Crisis, digitalisation and the future of the internet. Info 14(6): 73-83.
Reinsch P (1911) Public international unions. Boston: Ginn Sandvine.
Rodgers DT (2000) Atlantic crossings. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Rogers W (1918) An American international and inter-colonial communications program. National Archives
and Records Administration. RG59, 574 D1, Box 4.
Ross EA (1910) The suppression of important news. Atlantic Monthly March, 303-311.
Ross EA (1908) Social psychology. New York: Macmillan.
Ross EA (1901) Social control. New York: Macmillan.
Samuelson P (2011) The Google book settlement as copyright reform, Wisconsin Law Review 478: 477-560.
Schiller H (1989) Culture Inc. New York: Oxford University.
Schiller H (1969) Mass communications and American empire. Boston: Beacon.
Schumpeter JA (1943/96) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London: Routledge.
Sklansky J (2000) Corporate property and social psychology. Radical History Review 76: 90-114.
Simonson P (2012) Charles Horton Cooley and the origins of U.S. communication study in political
economy. Democratic Communique 25(1): 1-22.
Simonson P and Weiman G (2003). Critical research at Columbia. In: Katz E, Peters J, Liebes T and Orloff
A (Eds) Canonic texts in media research. London: Polity, pp. 12-38.
Simpson C (1994) Science of coercion. New York: Oxford University.
Smith A (1776/2000) The wealth of nations. New York: Modern Library.
Sklar M (1988) The corporate reconstruction of American capitalism, 1890-1916. New York: Cambridge
University.
Skorup B and Thierer A (2012) Uncreative destruction. Working Paper, Mercatus Centre, George Mason
University.
Winseck 113
Winseck D (2009) Pursuing the holy grail. European Journal of Communication 13(3): 337-373.
Winseck D and Pike R (2007) Communication and empire. Durnham, NC: Duke University.
Zuboff S (2015) Big other: Surveillance capitalism and the prospects of an information civilization. Journal
of Information Technology 30(1): 75–89.